Skip to main content

Full text of "From Victory To Defeat: China's Socialist Road and Capitalist Reversal"

See other formats


FROM VICTORY TO DEFEAT 


CHINA'S SOCIALIST ROAD AND CAPITALIST REVERSAL 


PAO-YU CHING 


FOREIGN LANGUAGES PRESS 


FOREIGN LANGUAGES PRESS 
Collection “New Roads” #1 
A collection directed by Christophe Kistler 


Contact — redspark.contact@protonmail.com 
https://foreignlanguages.press 


Paris, 2019 
1st Edition 


ISBN: 978-2-491182-01-4 


This book is under license Attribution-ShareAlike 4.0 International 
(CC BY-SA 4.0) 


https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-sa/4.0/ 


Preface 
J. Moufawad-Paul 


Introduction 


Question I. 


Question II. 
Question II. (A) 
Question II. (B) 


Question III. 


Question IV. 


Question V. 


Question VI. 


Question VII. 


Contents 


Karl Marx anticipated that socialist revolution 
was likely to occur first in countries where 
capitalism had reached a more advanced stage. 
Why did socialist revolution occur first in 
Russia and then in China where capitalism 
was only in the early stage of development? 


How do we determine if China’s development 
from 1956 to 1978 was socialist? 


How were the relations of production changed 
in the state-owned industrial sector? 


How did the relations of production change in 
the collectively-owned agricultural sector? 


How did the superstructure change from feu- 
dal and capitalist to socialist from 1949 to 
1978, and how important was the Cultural 
Revolution to this change? 


What were some additional achievements 
made during China’s socialist development? 


What was China’s socialist development strat- 
egy? How was China’s socialist development 
different from colonial and semi-colonial 
countries pursuing capitalist development? 


What Challenges and Difficulties did China 


Face During Socialist Construction? 


What has happened to China and Chinese 
people after the counter-revolutionaries seized 
power in 1976? 


Seizing Political Power and Implementing 
Capitalist Reform 


15 


19 


20 


30 


39 


51 


a0 


70 


84 


84 


Conclusion 


Fundamental Changes in the Relations of Pro- 
duction 


Fundamental Changes in the Superstructure 


China’s Capitalist “Reform and Opening Up” 
and the World of Imperialism 


China’s Capitalist “Reform and Opening Up” 
and China’s Working Class Struggles 


Impact of China’s Capitalist “Reform and 
Opening Up” on Chinas Land, Resources, 


and Environment 


China’s Capitalist “Reform and Opening Up” 
and the Deep Internal Contradictions 


China and Chinese People in the Future of 
World Socialist Revolution 


85 


89 
92 


102 


110 


111 


118 


119 


Preface 


Preface 
J. Moufawad-Paul 


When I was approached to write a preface for this book I was—by 
one of those strange coincidences that idealists believe are more significant 
than they actually are—rereading Rethinking Socialism, which Pao-yu Ching 
co-authored with Deng-Yuan Hsu in 1998. I had assigned selections from 
that extended essay in a course I was teaching and was preparing my reading 
notes. The request for this preface, then, came right at the moment when | 
was being struck with the clarity of Ching’s thought in her 2017 introduc- 
tion of the second edition of Rethinking Socialism, which I was only just 
reading. Such clarity would also be recognized by my students, the best of 
whom found her reframing of the question of “socialist failure” as “socialist 
defeat” refreshing and, despite only being assigned selections, avidly con- 
sumed the entire work. | assigned this text in a course about the philosophy 
of Marxism and post-Marxism following a constellation of philosophical 
works, encouraging students to engage with a work of recent radical political 
economy in relation to the more abstract texts they had spent weeks reading. 

The above anecdote might explain why a philosopher such as myself 
is writing an introduction to a book that is ostensibly a work of political 
economy. Ching’s work generates categorical distinctions that demand phil- 
osophical investigation. Since my training is not in political economy but in 
philosophy, my appreciation of Ching’s work functions according to a philo- 
sophical register. That is, | am interested in the ways in which she uses these 
the categories of political economy to draw clear demarcations in thought so 
as to force important decisions in the thinking and practice of politics. As a 
Marxist I am of the opinion that political economy is useful for demystifying 
its object of analysis with the intention of demanding revolutionary trans- 
formation. This is what Marx did, after all, when he left the realm of abstract 
philosophy and entered the battleground of bourgeois economic theory. 

The Marxist (political) economist ought to understand what is at stake 
in their work, that economic perspectives are determined by class struggle, 
and thus be able to establish the revolutionary standpoint. The practice of 
philosophy is useful insofar as it can compare differing attempts to establish 
such a standpoint and clarify the reasons why one position is better than 
another. Which is all to say that P’'ve been drawn to Ching’s work, as I have 


1 


From Victory to Defeat 


been drawn to the work of political economists such as Samir Amin, because 
its concern with the practice of making revolution has always rendered it 
clear and thus philosophically salient. Therefore, my prefatory comments 
will be a small philosophical intervention designed to think about this new 
work of Ching’s according to the larger concerns of the Marxist terrain, to 
interpret its meaning in the context of what all intellectual labor within this 
terrain should be about: revolution, socialist transformation, and the road 
to communism. 


Ching’s work to date 


‘Those readers already familiar with Ching’s contributions to date, and 
who are reading From Victory to Defeat: China’ Socialist Road and Capitalist 
Reversal because of her past work, can skip ahead since you can probably 
guess what I’m about to write by way of introduction. But if you are a reader 
who is encountering Ching for the first time, then I feel it is necessary to 
introduce her main concerns, the primary object of her critical thought, so 
that you can appreciate this book in relation to her total project. 

Generally speaking, Ching’s work has been about examining the defeat 
of socialism in the last great world historical revolution, the Chinese Revolu- 
tion, unveiling the meaning of revisionism to think through the problematic 
of socialist transformation. By examining the line struggle in the Chinese 
Revolution, and the eventual victory of the Liu-Deng line, Ching has not 
only sought to establish key insights about what socialism as a process for 
generating communism should be, she has also revealed the ways in which 
the revisionism encountered in the course of such a process can be known. 
That is, she has rigorously exposed the meaning of both a socialist and revi- 
sionist political economy, the latter of which leads to capitalist restoration 
and the defeat of socialism by waving the red flag to bring down the red flag. 

Before From Victory to Defeat there are two books available in English, 
along with numerous articles, which form the sequence of Ching’s thought. 
The first of these books is Rethinking Socialism (1998), co-authored with 
Deng-Yuan Hsu, which focused on the question of socialist transition in 
light of China's great reversal. The second is Revolution and Counterrevo- 
lution (2012), which examined the capitalist road taken by China and the 
struggles waged in the pursuit of this road. Finally, in her essay The Cur- 
rent Phase of Imperialism and China (2017), Ching outlined China’s impe- 


Preface 


rialist ambitions in contrast to its socialist past. Now we have From Victory 
to Defeat: Chinas Socialist Road and Capitalist Reversal, which is the most 
focused exposé to date of what the revisionist Liu-Deng road has wrought 
upon a social formation that was at one point of time the highest expression 
of socialist transition. Such an exposure not only demonstrates how the path 
of socialist transition can be compromised and reversed, it also reveals what 
is at stake and teaches us what needs to be done so as to rigorously pursue 
communism. 

Moreover, From Victory to Defeat picks up where Ching left off with 
her 2017 introduction to Rethinking Socialism: the aforementioned neces- 
sity of thinking of the capitalist reversal as the result of a “defeat” rather 
than a “failure” of socialism; the importance of rejecting Eurocentric Marxist 
orthodoxy regarding the “failure” of socialist revolutions (i.e. the problem 
was that these revolutions happened in “backwards” modes of productions 
rather than progressing from a developed capitalism with a proper bour- 
geois-proletariat class structure), exemplified in the work of authors such as 
Ellen Meiksins Wood. 


From Victory to Defeat: China’s Socialist Road and Capitalist Rever- 
sal 


As with any text it is always important to first understand what the 
text zs in order to assess its merits. For example, if a book intended to teach 
readers how to play chess did not adequately accomplish its intentions we 
would say that it is not a very good book; those defending it as excellent 
because it possessed a decent chapter on the history of the game would not 
have a very good argument regarding the book’s overall worth because the 
book as a whole did not fulfill what it sought to accomplish. So what is 
Pao-yu Ching’s From Victory to Defeat: China’s Socialist Road and Capitalist 
Reversak? 

First of all, it is not a work of descriptive political economy regarding 
both China’s socialist past and its current present. Or rather, it is not simply 
a work of descriptive political economy. It does indeed describe the political 
economic orders of China from the Mao period to the present, and defi- 
nitely proves the revisionist distance between the two, but this description is 
not primarily about description. But From Victory to Defeat is not intended 
to be merely such a work. 


From Victory to Defeat 


Secondly, it is not merely a historiography of China from the time of 
Mao Zedong to Xi Jinping. That is, its intention is not to simply present us 
with a historical narrative—counter to both the Western bourgeois and Chi- 
nese revisionist historical narratives—of the revisionist fall from grace that 
Chinese socialism experienced, the decades long capitalist road upon which 
the waystation of Xi’s government has been built. Not that constructing such 
an historical counter-narrative is not important, nor can we discount the fact 
that Ching significantly contributes to this counter-narrative with this book. 
But if we treated From Victory to Defeat as merely a work of revolutionary 
counter-history about contemporary China we would again miss out on 
what it intends to be through its discussion of Chinese history. 

Then what is Ching’s From Victory to Defeat: Chinas Socialist Road and 
Capitalist Reversal? It is a political intervention, using the tools of political 
economy and historiography that lays out the case for the necessity of com- 
munist revolution. The frame of China’s contemporary history is significant 
because the Chinese Revolution was the most recent world historical revo- 
lution—the current conjuncture remains within its shadow despite those 
Marxists who would pretend otherwise—and thus excavating the meaning 
of how its socialist construction was reversed is a warning of the obstacles 
that any potential socialist state will face. Figuring out how to establish 
such socialisms in the shadow cast by the Chinese Revolution, though, is an 
immediate necessity according to Ching. After all, she begins this book with 
a description of the capitalist nightmare and proclaims, in the opening para- 
graphs, the antinomy of “socialism or barbarism” (referencing both Engels 
and Luxemburg), which I have also argued should be the way to think com- 
munist necessity—and neither myself nor Ching are alone in this insight. 
It is the thought of all communists and communist projects that seek to 
demarcate themselves from business as usual. 

Hence, From Victory to Defeat demarcates the pursuit of socialism 
from revisionism, using the tools of political economy and historiography 
to explicate this demarcation, and thus delineates itself from Eurocentric 
approaches as well as those approaches that seek to naturalize so-called “actu- 
ally existing socialism.” The point is to learn from the distance between the 
most recent world historical revolution and its reversal in order to understand 
how to establish socialism now and be prepared for its pitfalls. Descriptive 
political economy and radical historiography are tools, and tools used very 
well, to accomplish this intervention. But the point is the intervention and 


4 


Preface 


the lines of demarcation it necessitates. 

Although there are many lessons Ching draws from the experience 
of the Chinese Revolution in the course of her intervention, I will examine 
only three points of interest that differentiate the socialist road from the 
capitalist road. These are points that are foundational to an anti-revisionist 
understanding of making communism. 

‘The first point is that socialist construction, just like the revolution 
that brings about a dictatorship of the proletariat, is not a dinner party. 
Mobilizing the masses to transform all aspects of society requires a great 
amount of creativity and foresight, as well as scientific wherewithal, to pro- 
duce the kind of economy, state, and culture that moves us towards a needs- 
based society. The revolution must continue at all levels of social existence 
and but also must advance according to communist ideology: it must be, as 
the old slogan went, both red and expert. 

‘The second point is that class struggle continues under socialism: a 
fact that Mao originally made clear, and the Maoism has declared a universal 
principle, but one that Ching demonstrates as empirically correct through 
her examination of the rise and fall of the Chinese Revolution. Socialism 
is fragile, its construction and persistence can always be compromised, and 
factions within the communist party itself can defeat the revolutionary line 
and re-orientate society towards the capitalist road. Such a defeat often hap- 
pens by “waving the red flag to bring down the red flag”—that is, by using 
socialist sounding language to enact anti-socialist reforms. This book con- 
tains snapshots of how that struggle was borne out, how socialism was con- 
structed through this struggle, and how it was eventually defeated when the 
revisionists began to win this class struggle under socialism. 

(A corollary to the second point is that socialism is not merely a word 
or a vague notion but a meaningful concept. We can know what social for- 
mations are socialist, or pursuing socialism, by knowing what socialism is, 
just as we can know, by the same token, the meaning of its opposite. Such a 
conception of socialism was thoroughly worked out in Rethinking Socialism 
but operates in this book as well, demonstrated by the differences between 
China’s Mao and Deng eras.) 

The third point is that even when a socialist revolution is defeated, if 
it has advanced far enough down the road to communism before the revi- 
sionist detour (and the Chinese Revolution, as Ching demonstrates here, 
advanced further than any other socialist revolution to date), then the legacy 


5 


From Victory to Defeat 


of socialism will remain and will be difficult to stamp out. This is because the 
masses, who were mobilized to construct socialism, remained mobilized, and 
the memory of this mobilization persists and is being passed down to suc- 
cessive generations. Every stage of capitalist reform in China has been forced 
to proceed against the masses interest and was a struggle for the capitalist 
roaders to establish. The final sections in this book that examine the Chinese 
anti-revisionist left today demonstrate that the legacy of the Chinese Revo- 
lution and the GPCR is a living memory for workers, peasants, and radical 
students. Even defeated revolutions do not easily die; when the masses are 
mobilized they understand when they are betrayed. 

This third point returns us to the importance of understanding that 
socialism was defeated rather than failed. For if socialism was an abject fail- 
ure then there would not be significant forces and struggles in formerly 
socialist countries coding themselves according to a doctrine of failure. For 
why would anyone raise the banner of “the God that failed”? Failure teaches 
those who failed that their way of doing things was erroneous. Such struggles 
would rather, as liberal pundits who blather on about China like to presume, 
resemble that faction of students in Tiananmen Square who were advocating 
for USAmerican style capitalism rather than the workers and peasants, in 
the same event who were raising the banner of Mao and demanding a return 
to the Cultural Revolution. Indeed, both Western pundits and the Chinese 
Government ignored the larger rebellion in Tiananmen, framing it around 
the neo-liberal student groups. Neither the Western media nor the Chinese 
government wanted to admit, though for oppositional reasons, that there 
was a socialist element to the rebellion. For if socialism was defeated rather 
than simply failed, it remains a live option, a vital legacy. 


Demarcating Communism 


When I began reading this book I had just finished reading the 
manuscript of the soon-to-be-published science-fiction novella, And Shall 
Machines Surrender, by my friend, occasional analogical inspiration, and 
sometimes collaborator, Benjanun Sriduangkaew. In that space opera novella 
a distant future 

Dyson Sphere utopia is named after Shenzhen, the special economic 
zone that Ching examines as paradigmatic to China’s capitalist Reform. 
What struck me was that the distance between Sriduangkaew’s fictional 


Preface 


Shenzhen Sphere and the actual Shenzhen was also the distance between the 
revisionist “Marxist-Leninist” delirium of “market socialism” and its reality. 
‘The science fiction, intergalactic Shenzhen possessed the stability and lack 
of poverty that the real Shenzhen does not since the latter has functioned to 
destabilize socialism and generate impoverishment. Those “Marxists” who 
maintain that China is socialist have a notion of post-Mao Reform that is 
akin to imagining future Dyson Spheres: that is, they have a completely 
fantastic and fictional understanding of reality. I would like to hope that 
some of them would read Ching’s book and change their perspective—that 
they would grasp the fictional and fantastical basis of their previous concep- 
tions—but I am also aware of the strength of revisionist ideology since it is 
the long shadow cast by capitalist ideology. 

But for those readers who want to learn from the actual lessons of the 
Chinese Revolution, if there is a single lesson that we can derive from this 
book, it is that socialism, as well as its communist destination, is indeed a 
live option and vital legacy. Ching presents us with a choice regarding the 
meaning of socialism: do we see it as simply a name that is meaningful 
insofar as it is attached to a number of actually existing regimes, or do we 
understand it as a concept that spills beyond this act of simplistic naming; is 
socialism merely a formality or does it possess real content? This antinomy 
does not imply that Ching, like so many academic Marxists, is trapped in 
the dilemma of rejecting the great socialist experiments because they do not 
resemble an ideal notion of socialism that exists only in the imagination of 
Marxist purists. She rejects this interpretation as well; her understanding of 
socialist transition grants that there were socialist revolutions. Her distinc- 
tion between name and concept and form and content is not an idealist 
exercise that bans all real world attempts of making socialism to the realm of 
the a priori doomed because they fail to satisfy some vague notion of Marxist 
puritanism. She has already told us that there were socialist formations, and 
there are reasons that they can qualify as such, but the reason they did not 
persist was because they were defeated. 

In the end, the line Pao-yu Ching draws between the name/concept 
and form/ content of socialism is also the line drawn between revisionism/ 
anti-revisionism and counter-revolution/revolution. If we want to even 
begin to think communism then this is precisely the line that needs to be 
demarcated. 


Introduction 


Introduction 


Today an overwhelming majority of people is struggling to survive 
from day to day or month to month. They face a bleak and hopeless future. 
The discontent of the masses of people has reached the highest since any 
time post World War II. Since the end of the war, imperialist countries have 
gone through many rounds of reform. Political representatives of the cap- 
italists, such as the social democrats, made repeated promises for a better 
society, which were then broken and their memories faded away. Since the 
late 1970s, after the latest neoliberal restructuring of the global capitalist 
system, the world capitalist system has gone through severe crises in the 
1980s, 1990s, with the worst crisis in 2008-2009, which has lasted for an 
entire decade. Today the living conditions of the working masses in impe- 
rialist countries have grown increasingly difficult. Labor productivity has 
increased substantially but workers’ wages have stagnated and benefits con- 
tinued to decline. At the same time, for most working people, jobs have 
become more precarious as more workers are employed on a temporary and 
part-time basis. Yet the basic cost of living, such as rent, food, utilities and 
other necessities of life has continued to rise, resulting in an accumulation 
of debt for workers and their families. Meanwhile the dominant capitalists, 
a tiny percent of the population, have accumulated an almost unimaginable 
amount of wealth and are living obscenely lavish lives. 

Moreover, the suffering of people in colonial and semi-colonial coun- 
tries has worsened. On top of many years of colonial rule, imperialist powers 
have continued their political and economic domination even after people 
in these countries fought and won their “independence.” The dream of the 
national bourgeoisie in these countries in the early post-war years to develop 
capitalism independently has been resoundingly smashed after the crises 
in 1982-85 and then in 1997-99. After rounds of restructuring by global 
monopoly capital, assisted by international financial institutions such as the 
International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank (WB), these coun- 
tries went through rounds of austerity programs to cut public health and 
education, already severely under-funded. The Structural Adjustment Pro- 
gram (SAP) imposed by the IMF on these debt-ridden countries demanded 
financial deregulation and privatization in order to facilitate the takeover of 
these assets by foreign capital. Labor reform programs forced these countries 


From Victory to Defeat 


to keep their labor market flexible including longer working hours, lowered 
wages and relaxed restrictions on other working conditions, as well as pre- 
vention of labor organizing. Even before the latest global neoliberal restruc- 
turing, colonial and semi-colonial countries had never established political 
or economic sovereignty. After the neoliberal restructuring they had little 
choice but to accept the conditions demanded by global monopoly capital, 
because their hope to develop their own economies no longer existed. They 
have since opened their borders for imports of foreign capital and commod- 
ities (including basic food) and have joined the new global division of labor 
by exporting products produced by cheap labor via the global supply chain. 

‘The appetite of monopoly capital is insatiable; it must assert control 
over all aspects of people’s lives in order to gain a “competitive advantage” 
over its rivals. Global monopoly capital has taken further steps to deprive 
people in colonial and semi-colonial countries the ability to produce goods 
for their own consumption by imposing rules set by capitalist representa- 
tives, such as the World Trade Organization (WTO), to protect the intellec- 
tual property rights of giant corporations. These multinational corporations 
from imperialist countries, such as Monsanto and others, take the seeds of 
crops and other plants cultivated and improved upon by many generations 
of peasants and genetically modify them to claim them as private property 
protected by the WTO’s intellectual property rights. Similarly large interna- 
tional pharmaceutical companies take ancient traditional medical remedies 
used by indigenous people and turn them into patent-protected profit mak- 
ing commodities. These international corporations take what used to belong 
to the commons, shared by all people in their communities for thousands 
of years, and turn it into privately owned monopolized profit-making com- 
modities. The consequence has been tens and even hundreds of millions of 
peasants in colonial and semi-colonial countries losing their ability to use 
their own seeds to produce food and medicine for survival. 

‘The insatiable need for capital to expand has led to overproduction 
that over-tills the land, over-grazes the pastures, over-fishes the rivers and sea, 
exhausts the planet’s resources and unleashes fatal amounts of chemicals and 
waste into the ground, air, and water, causing critical damage to the earth 
and people’s health. Policies carried out by the representatives of monopoly 
capital are destructive and brutal. The latest neoliberal restructuring swept 
away all the barriers for its global expansion causing more and more people 
to realize that they must fight back if they do not want to be swallowed alive 


10 


Introduction 


by ever more powerful monopoly capital. 

In addition to brutal political and economic oppression there have 
also been seemingly endless wars. In order to maintain its hegemony, the 
United States has used its superior military power to impose wars on rela- 
tively defenseless nations and peoples. The destruction caused by these end- 
less wars has gone far beyond the previous two World Wars. I think we have 
again arrived to the point where Friedrich Engels concluded, “if the whole of 
modern society is not to perish, a revolution in the mode of production and 
distribution must take place.”’ And what Luxemburg reminded us a hun- 
dred years ago when she wrote, “bourgeois society stands at the crossroad, 
either transition to socialism or regression into barbarism.”” Revolutionaries 
heeded these warnings; they did not sit idly by waiting for capitalism to 
destroy them. Revolutionaries in Russia under Lenin’s leadership took up 
arms and won the first nation-wide socialist revolution. 

The 1917 Russian Revolution and the 1949 Chinese Revolution were 
the two most important historical events in the 20" century. The Cuban 
Revolution succeeded in 1959 and though it was smaller in scale, it had 
significant influence especially in Latin American countries. These heroic 
revolutions were all led by communist parties, the vanguard of the proletar- 
iat. Now another hundred years later the Russian revolution and the Chinese 
revolution have both been defeated. The Communist Party in the USSR 
embarked on revisionism in 1956 and the Communist Party in China ini- 
tiated capitalist reform in 1978. In 2018, one hundred years after Luxem- 
burg’s warning to modern society, all of humankind is again facing total 
destruction. What are we to do? 

We have the choice of either burying our heads in the sand and 
accepting the verdict of leading capitalist propaganda that socialism has 
failed and capitalism has won, thus signaling the end of history, or we can 
choose socialism over barbarism like our courageous forbearers in 1917 and 
1949 and many of our contemporaries today. They chose to struggle against 
capitalism and for socialism. The current reality could not be clearer and the 
choice is entirely ours. 

On the one hand, we are in a better position than revolutionaries 
before our time, because they were able to prove that armed struggle with 


' Anti-Dubring, the International Publisher’s (New York) edition of 1987, 146. 


* Rosa Luxemburg attributed what she said to Friedrich Engels in her “Junius Pam- 
phlet” of 1916. 


11 


From Victory to Defeat 


the goal of achieving communism could be won. ‘The dictatorship of the 
proletariat was proven possible. This has given us tremendous confidence 
and optimism. On the other hand, at some point on the road of socialist 
development, revisionists seized political power and reversed the develop- 
ment from socialism to capitalism. There have been some analyses of why 
and how socialist development was aborted. However, these explanations 
have not satisfied critics who think that socialism may look good on paper 
but that it is incompatible with human nature. According to them, pointing 
to the many communist party officials who enriched themselves by rob- 
bing the wealth from the working masses, once people possess power they 
are invariably corrupted. In other words former revolutionaries turned into 
new exploiters and oppressors. We certainly cannot deny that corruption 
happened countless times in socialist countries. However, there were many 
more examples of powerful communist party members who sacrificed them- 
selves (some with their lives) to advance the interests of people toward their 
common goal of communism. The statement of “power corrupts” is not a 
statement of truth. Human nature is vot the problem behind corruption but 
the abuse of power is. 

Although the concept of “power corrupts” has had a long history 
among the Left, in recent years where the anarchist movements are strong 
(mainly in imperialist countries), the fear of power itself has also become 
more prevalent.’ Such fear has rendered the Left impotent in their struggle 
against the centrally organized and highly concentrated power of capital. In 
many left organizations in these countries, power is considered too concen- 
trated unless it is shared equally among all of its members. ‘The leaders, if 
there are any, should only be allowed to make decisions when they are based 
on the consensus of all members in the group. While it is true that abuses 
occur in organizations with only centralism without democracy, it is equally 
true that an organization is rendered totally powerless if no one is permitted 
to lead for fear of the concentration of power. The result has been that such 
“horizontally organized” bodies cannot generate leadership to plan for the 


> The “power corrupts” debate has a long history. It has existed between the socialist 
(both utopian and Marxist) and the anarchists since the 19 century everywhere in 
the world. What’s new now is that since the end of the anti-revisionist wave (the early 
80s) the anarchists have grown stronger in imperialist countries and have broadly 
spread those ideas in the Left and in academia (with such rhetoric as “radical subjectiv- 
ity” in philosophy, “workers’ self-management” in economy, and “radical feminism, 
etc.) Nowadays these ideas are particularly cherished by post-modernists. 


12 


Introduction 


long-term in their fight against powerful capital. These organizations often 
degenerate to the point where members engage in endless debates and only 
at the level of tactics. 

If there had not been centralism there could not have been any social- 
ist revolution or any socialist development. That said, centralism without 
democracy indeed bred abuses in former socialist countries. Therefore, the 
question is not “how power corrupts” but “how corrupting power can be 
checked and corrected.” 

‘The reality we face today is that after one hundred years the two major 
and several smaller scaled attempts to build a new socialist mode of produc- 
tion and distribution with the goal of reaching communism, were aborted. 
Historically, achievement in human development has always been a con- 
tinuation of contributions made by successive generations. On the road of 
historical progression there will always be advances and retreats. Revolution- 
aries in our current era need to take the progress and defeats toward the goal 
of communism as precious lessons learned. We are fortunate, because we 
have not only inherited the wealth of revolutionary theory by Marx, Lenin, 
and Mao—we have also inherited the concrete experiences of building a 
socialist society in the Soviet Union from 1917 to 1956 and in China from 
1949 to 1978, as well as their subsequent defeats. Such a wealth of knowl- 
edge accumulated by the lives and deaths of past revolutionaries has been 
passed on to us, allowing us to study and understand how they succeeded, 
what their accomplishments were, what challenges they faced, and how and 
why they were eventually defeated. 

In the following sections, I present an analysis of China’s socialist rev- 
olution and socialist development by positing several questions and then 
attempting to answer them. I chose this format because, from my observa- 
tion, revolutionaries in general and Maoists in particular have formulated 
these questions and are searching for answers. In this presentation I hope 
to analyze the achievements of China’s socialist development as well as the 
difficulties and challenges the Chinese revolutionaries faced when building 
a new society that fundamentally changed the economic base and the super- 
structure. 

Maoists today rightfully regard the Great Proletarian Cultural Revo- 
lution as the most important event in the Chinese revolution. “Bombarding 
the headquarters” undoubtedly ignited the revolutionary passion and enthu- 
siasm of the Chinese people, especially in young people, as well as revolu- 


13 


From Victory to Defeat 


tionaries in the rest of the world. However, it is just if not more important 
to have a deeper understanding of what the Cultural Revolution in China 
was trying to defend. Without the Cultural Revolution, the counterrevolu- 
tionaries would have been able to carry out their capitalist reversal in 1966 
instead of 1978. If that had been the case, all the socialist programs put in 
place during the Cultural Revolution, such as changes made in industrial 
organization, in education and health, in arts and culture, and practicing 
democracy and much more, would have not been put into practice. More- 
over, all the basic and concrete progress made before 1966 in the economic 
base and in the superstructure for socialist development would have been 
smashed—not during the years since 1978—but more than a decade earlier. 

What I would like to emphasize here is: when revolutionaries decide 
to choose socialism over barbarism, and when they struggle against capital- 
ism and for socialism, we need to have a deep and concrete understanding of 
what socialism is. Simply put: how and in what way socialism is the antith- 
esis of capitalism. 


14 


Question I. 


Question I. 


Karl Marx anticipated that socialist revolution was likely to occur first 
in countries where capitalism had reached a more advanced stage. Why 
did socialist revolution occur first in Russia and then in China where 
capitalism was only in the early stage of development? 


As the title of his most important work suggests—Capital, Vol. 1 A 
Critical Analysis of Capitalist Production—the focus of Karl Marx’s analysis 
was on capitalist production. From his analysis he foresaw that the prole- 
tariat in countries where capitalism had developed would lead the socialist 
revolution. At a commemoration of the 150" anniversary of The Communist 
Manifesto, Ellen Meiksins Wood, then editor of the Monthly Review, offered 
her explanation of the historic “failures” of socialism. Wood’s premise was 
that socialism has failed because attempts were not made “in the kind of 
society that Marx regarded as the right foundation for socialist transforma- 
tion.“ It is true that Marx did not anticipate that socialist revolution would 
occur in Russia where capitalism was only in the early stage of development, 
because he did not foresee the emergence of imperialism, which changed 
the revolutionary situation in the world. In /mperialism: the Highest Stage 
of Capitalism Lenin made clear how the opportunity existed objectively for 
countries at the weakest links of the world imperialist system to make social- 
ist revolution, even if capitalism in these countries was still in an early stage 
of development. 

Imperialist countries fought furiously to prevent colonial and 
semi-colonial countries from developing capitalism so that they could con- 
tinue pillaging resources from them for the raw materials they needed for 
industrialization. Had less developed countries begun to develop capitalism 
independently, advanced capitalist countries would have lost access to raw 
materials as well as export markets for their surplus capital and surplus prod- 
ucts. Therefore, imperialist countries used brute force to suppress struggles 
for national liberation and development around the world. Even after former 
colonies gained their independence in the 19 and the 20" centuries, today 
they still do not have political sovereignty. Without political sovereignty they 


* Ellen Meiksins Wood on the “Zhe Communist Manifesto After 150 Years” published 
in the May 1998 issue of Monthly Review, 29. 


15 


From Victory to Defeat 


have been denied economic sovereignty, i.e. the freedom to use their own 
resources to develop their own countries. 

The lack of independent capitalist development in these countries 
resulted in a weak national bourgeois class. The lack of independent capi- 
talist development and a weak national bourgeoisie are opposite sides of the 
same coin. A weak national bourgeoisie means that this class is too weak to 
fend off the invasion of foreign capital and so weak politically, that they need 
the support of the domestic landowning class to rule nationally. This is the 
reason why many of these countries have not been able to carry out genuine 
land reform to end feudalism. In other words the national bourgeoisie is not 
strong enough to lead a democratic revolution—a democratic revolution 
necessary for the development of capitalism. 

The Russian Revolution in 1917 demonstrated that the proletar- 
iat could successfully launch a socialist revolution. It proved to the world 
that the working class did not need to wait for the bourgeoisie to complete 
the democratic revolution and to develop capitalism before they liberated 
themselves and charted their own path of development. In the famous Chi- 
nese revolutionary drama The East is Red, an announcer gives an historical 
account of the Chinese revolution exclaiming, “The October Revolution 
sent us the teaching of Marx and Lenin. Follow the Russians, this is our 
way!” It’s difficult to emphasize enough how much the Russian Revolution 
inspired working people of the world. The Chinese people under the lead- 
ership of the Chinese Communist Party followed the heroic example set by 
the Russian revolutionaries. 

In January 1940 in the midst of defending China against the Japa- 
nese imperialist invasion Mao wrote On New Democracy.’ In this essay Mao 
further elaborated on the meaning and importance of a new democratic 
revolution led by the proletariat. Mao analyzed the historical characteristics 
of China and how China's revolution would be an integral part of the world 
revolution. Mao asked, “Should China follow the West through the dicta- 
torship of the bourgeoisie?” He opposed this idea, writing, “In the first place 
international capitalism or imperialism will not permit the establishment 
in China of a capitalist society under a bourgeois dictatorship. Indeed the 
history of modern China is a history of imperialist aggression, of imperialist 


> Mao oe On New Democracy, January 1940, Selected Works of Mao Tse-tung, 
Vol II, 339-384, Foreign Languages Press, 1977. 


16 


Question I. 
opposition to China’s independence and to her development of capitalism.”° 
Mao illustrated (after the victory of the first socialist revolution) that the 
international situation had become a struggle between capitalism and social- 
ism, in which capitalism was in decline and socialism was on the rise. 

Mao further asserted that socialism would not permit the dictatorship 
of the bourgeoisie in China. He said that all the imperialist powers in the 
world were China’s enemies and that China could not possibly gain its inde- 
pendence without the assistance of socialist countries and the international 
proletariat, meaning the Soviet Union and the proletariat in Japan, Britain, 
the United States, France, Germany, Italy and other countries, through their 
struggle against capitalism. Today socialist countries no longer exist, but the 
truth remains that the success of any socialist revolution in any country 
requires the support and participation of the international proletariat in all 
countries. As monopoly capital from different capitalist countries unites to 
pursue its common interests, the solidarity of international working people 
is a necessity now more than ever. 

During the Chinese revolution, the Chinese Communist Party, van- 
guard of the proletariat, was very clear from the beginning that the prole- 
tariat-led new democratic revolution would proceed to a socialist revolu- 
tion with the goal of reaching communism. After the 1949 victory the new 
Chinese government seized the assets of the Kuomintang and confiscated 
assets of foreign capitalists and compradors. Together these assets accounted 
for 80% of China’s total assets. The remaining 20% consisted of factories 
and commercial enterprises owned by the national bourgeoisie. In 1949 the 
principle contradiction in Chinese society was between the landowning class 
and the vast majority of the Chinese people. After Land Reform was com- 
pleted in 1953 the principle contradiction changed to one between the cap- 
italists who still owned the factories and other commercial enterprises and 
the proletariat. By 1956, through different programs, assets in these privately 
owned enterprises were successfully transferred to the State. 

Almost 70 years after the Chinese revolution it has become even more 
obvious that colonial and semi-colonial countries do not have any chance to 
develop capitalism independent of the imperialist countries. Starting in the 
1980s the bourgeoisie in these countries began to realize that their dreams 
to develop their own independent capitalism would never be realized, so 


® Tbid. 


17 


From Victory to Defeat 


they sold the interests of their countries to international monopoly capital 
and took a cut in the profits. There may still be a few of them stubbornly 
fighting on. However, in today’s imperialism the national bourgeoisie is a 
contradictory and antiquated concept. Working masses in these countries 
can only rely on themselves for the development of their countries with the 
goal of improving their lives and of building a better society for their future. 
Revolutionaries in these countries have no other choice but to organize and 
be part of the worldwide socialist revolution. 


18 


Question II. 


Question II. 


How do we determine if China’s development from 1956 to 1978 was 
socialist? 


In 1956 the ownership of the means of production in China’s indus- 
trial enterprises was transferred to the State. At the conclusion of Land 
Reform in 1953 the collectivization of agriculture began and People’s Com- 
munes were formed in 1958. According to the analysis my co-author Deng- 
yuan Hsu and I made in Rethinking Socialism, this transfer of ownership by 
itself was not an indication that China had begun to be socialist. Whether 
China proceeded to develop socialism or capitalism depended on what hap- 
pened after the means of production were transferred to the State and after 
the formation of the People’s Communes. Therefore, an account of concrete 
policies carried out after 1956 is necessary. From 1956 to 1976 the CCP 
pushed forward concrete policies that fundamentally changed the relations 
of production in both China’s industrial and agricultural sectors, making 
them socialist.” There were also basic changes in the superstructure. Funda- 
mental changes in the relations of production (the ownership and control 
in the means of production) and fundamental changes in the superstructure 
(political, ideological and cultural) are basic yardsticks to determine whether 
a society is capitalist or socialist, as explained below. 


From Victory to Defeat 


Question IT. (A) 


How were the relations of production changed in the state-owned in- 
dustrial sector? 


A set of concrete policies fundamentally changed the relations of pro- 
duction in the State-owned industrial enterprises: (1) phasing out commod- 
ity production, and (2) phasing out labor power as a commodity. 


Phasing out commodity production in state-owned enterprises 


During China’s socialist transition the State decided what and how 
much each industrial enterprise produced according to a national plan, which 
was based on the current and future needs of the people and the country. 
‘The State decided on investment plans to replace old machinery/equipment 
and additional investment for expanded production. ‘The State also provided 
the enterprise raw materials, machinery and equipment at pre-determined 
prices, and it “purchased” the outputs produced also at predetermined prices. 
‘The individual enterprise handed over any “excess revenue” over its “expen- 
ditures” to the State. The amount of this “excess revenue” was not considered 
“profit,” because the price of its inputs and outputs were artificially set by the 
State. This “excess revenue” was not used as an indicator to judge how well 
the enterprise was run. The measure used to judge the efficiency of the enter- 
prise was a comparison with past records—whether the enterprise produced 
more and better outputs at a faster rate, and if they managed to conserve 
more resources. Thus, “profit” and “loss,” important indicators in a capitalist 
economy ceased to have any meaning. This was the method by which state- 
owned enterprises were divorced from profit maximization. 

When commodity production was being phased out of the state sec- 
tor, the law of value (equal value exchange) lost its function to regulate the 
economy. In a capitalist economy market prices serve the function of reg- 
ulating supply and demand and prices have the function of directing what 
to produce and how resources are allocated. In a capitalist society resources 
go to where the production yields the highest rates of profit. When the state 
sector was phasing out commodity production in socialist China, the law of 
value ceased to direct the resources to different kinds of production. Instead, 
the economic plan did. The economic plan made it possible to change the 


20 


Question II. (A) 


purpose of production from profit maximization to producing use value for 
the satisfaction of the needs of people and the needs of the country (both 
current and future needs). 

In socialist China the economic plan determined how resources were 
allocated for the production of consumer goods such as food, clothing, 
healthcare and housing, etc. or for the production of producer goods such 
as machinery, equipment, infrastructure and buildings. The economic plan 
had to be carefully and deliberately considered to balance allocating very 
scarce resources between producing consumer goods, which satisfied the 
current needs of the population, and investment goods, which increased 
the capacity for future production. Moreover, among different kinds of con- 
sumer goods, preference was given to the most urgently needed consumer 
goods, such as food, clean drinking water, clothing and housing, as well as 
basic services, such as health care and education, etc. In the economic plan 
these basic products and services were priced artificially low so all urban 
residents could afford to buy them.* On the other hand in the early stage 
of development, other consumer products, such as wristwatches were con- 
sidered “luxury” items, so the price for watches was set artificially high (not 
reflecting the costs of production), at say 100 RMB. At this price it took the 
average income worker a couple of years to save enough to buy a watch. In 
an early stage of development only small amounts of resources were allocated 
to produce goods like watches. 

Among producer goods, heavy industry that produced machinery and 
equipment was given high priority, because it was the foundation of indus- 
trialization. Heavy industry produced machinery for light industries such as 
textiles. However, during industrialization in the Soviet Union, too much 
emphasis was placed on heavy industry at the expense of light industry and 
agriculture, and the result was shortages of food and other consumer goods. 
China learned from the experiences of the Soviet Union and strove not to 
repeat its mistakes. Mao wrote On the Ten Major Relationships in 1956 when 
industrialization just began.? The first major relationship was the relation- 
ship between heavy industry and light industry and between industry and 
agriculture. Here Mao wrote, “The emphasis in our country’s construction 


8 In cities food and cloth aaa were rationed and sold at low prices to ensure 
every resident could afford to buy them. 


” Mao Zedong, On the Ten Major Relationships, April 25, 1956, Selected Works of Mao 
Tse-tung, Vol. V, Foreign Languages Press, 1977. 


21 


From Victory to Defeat 


is on heavy industry. The production of means of production must be given 
priority.”’° But later in the next paragraph Mao cautioned that China should 
not repeat the USSR’s (and Eastern European countries’) mistake of placing 
a “lop-sided” stress on heavy industry at the neglect of agriculture and light 
industry, resulting in a shortage of goods and unstable currency. He advo- 
cated for economic planning that carefully considered the balance between 
industry and agriculture as well as between heavy industry and light industry. 

Of course, in drawing up the massive economic plan for the entire 
country, people made mistakes; it was a very complicated endeavor encom- 
passing many sectors of the economy and the relationships between these 
sectors. However the damage of those mistakes could be minimized if they 
were quickly discovered and corrected. A successful economic plan took 
constant adjustments and readjustments and people became more skilled by 
drawing on past experiences. Capitalist propaganda relentlessly claims that 
relying on the blind forces of the market achieves better results compared to 
a carefully and consciously planned economy. This is simply untrue. 

Only under socialism do we move away from producing commodities 
for the sake of maximizing profits. When we contrast the planned economy 
with the capitalist market economy we can understand the superiority of 
socialism. This paper explains the irrational and disastrous results of cap- 
italist economy dictated by the blind forces of the market where produc- 
tion of commodities is based on profit maximization, even more acute in 
the age of imperialism—the last stage of capitalism. In more recent decades 
damage done to colonial and semi-colonial country economies have become 
even more severe after international monopoly capital broke down all bar- 
riers and expanded to every corner of the world. After their economies were 
forcibly integrated into the domain where international monopoly capital 
dominated, they lost control over their resources. The law of value applied in 
this domain has taken away the people’s rights to simply live. Here are some 
concrete examples. 

We see many cities in the world—even cities in poor countries— 
where modern high-rises and six-lane highways exist side-by-side with urban 
slums occupied by homeless people living in deplorable conditions. These 
countries often lack the resources to build the most essential infrastructure, 
such as water purifying plants, because their first priority is to use a large 


10 Tbid. 


22 


Question II. (A) 


percentage of its income to pay the interest on debts they owe to foreign 
banks and international financial institutions. Moreover, in the era of neo- 
liberalism these countries have been forced to agree to dismantle any barriers 
to foreign investment. Some of the very first foreign investments that rushed 
in were often large soda pop companies such as Coca-Cola and Pepsi-Cola, 
because the amount of investment to build bottling plants is very low, while 
the profits are very high. These giant US soda pop companies simply bottle 
sugar water with their secret formula protected by WTO patent rights and 
wait for the profits to roll in. The poor who cannot afford to buy soda or 
bottled water have to drink contaminated water and suffer many waterborne 
diseases, because their governments don't have the funds to build water treat- 
ment plants. Is the market mechanism really a rational way to allocate a 
country’s resources when people are being denied clean water while large 
multinationals are reaping high profits? Wouldn't people have been better 
off if their economy had been planned and building water treatment plants 
was given top priority? 

‘There are many examples to show that relying on market forces has 
produced detrimental results for people in colonial and semi-colonial coun- 
tries suffering from high unemployment and low income. Their rulers have 
surrendered to the power of global monopoly capital and bought the lie 
that in the today’s globalized world a country can find its niche in the inter- 
national market based on its comparative advantages and then just export 
commodities to become prosperous. The result is that many countries pro- 
duce similar products and the export prices of these products plummet. 
One example is when the global market was flooded a few years ago with 
exported watches, with China in the lead. Prices of watches dropped to a 
ridiculously low. Once someone in the United States showed me his watch 
collection—one hundred watches of different styles and colors displayed in 
a very large fancy case. He proudly boasted that his collection did not cost 
him very much; middle-income people in imperialist countries who are not 
rich enough to own a fleet of expensive cars or a fancy big house can now 
afford a collection of watches. A watch collection is a clear case of commod- 
ity fetish, where the watch as a commodity is completely divorced from its 
use value, which is to tell time. This clear case demonstrates how the alloca- 
tion of resources is distorted in imperialism. When following international 
market forces, too many colonial and semi-colonial countries over-allocate 
their resources to produce commodities for export—so that people in impe- 


23 


From Victory to Defeat 


rialist countries can collect them at a low cost to satisfy their fetishes—and 
under-allocate resources to produce goods that their people urgently need, 
such as food, clean water, basic health, education, and housing. 

Moreover, the market is irrational when it comes to critical decisions 
about new investment and technological change. A business in a capitalist 
economy must constantly expand in order to maintain or increase its market 
share. If a business fails to do so and its market share shrinks, at some point it 
has to declare bankruptcy. Therefore, constant expansion is a necessity in the 
world of business under capitalism. Expanding a business means constantly 
developing new products, adopting new technology and investing in new 
production plants. The result is that often factories are abandoned while they 
are still in good condition and could be used to produce useful products. 
Capitalist propaganda has us believe that constant and mindless phasing out 
and discarding of old products, old technology, and old plants at the speed 
required by the market is a sign of progress. Actually the exact opposite is true. 
Only when we as humans take control of our own destinies can we rationally 
and consciously make decisions about when to replace old plants with new 
ones by weighing the usefulness of the old plant, the resources needed to 
produce new plants, and the consequences to the environment when shut- 
ting down the old ones. 

Here is a concrete example of how a real business under capitalism 
makes decisions about when to invest in new products: Andy Grove, former 
president of the major high-tech firm Intel, explains why they were already 
working on several new models to replace their next generation chips even 
before they were launched as such: “It’s the cannibal strategy; we eat our 
children and do it faster and faster. That is how we keep our lead.”"' All high- 
tech businesses have adopted the same strategy. When the iPhone first came 
out Apple proudly unveiled its innovative new product. But Apple soon had 
to render the first iPhone obsolete by putting out the iPhones 2, 3, 4, etc. 
Apple is now selling the iPhone X. Propaganda for capitalism defends such 
waste by saying, “planned obsolescence is the hallmark of progress.” 

In addition to “planned obsolescence” that continuously squanders 
the earth’s precious resources, there is the added destruction brought upon 
by repeated business cycles. During the upturn phase of the cycle businesses 
must prepare themselves for further expansion, so they feverishly add more 


4" hetps://www.wired.com/1998/03/inside-intels-new-ceo/ 


24 


Question IT. (A) 


productive capacity knowing that this excess capacity will be destroyed when 
the economy goes south. Since the later part of the 20" century the business 
cycle has become shorter due to the more speculative nature of investment. 
‘The destructive power of capital on the environment multiplied in the era of 
neoliberalism when colonial and semi-colonial countries accepted the rules 
set by global monopoly capital, removing all barriers for foreign capital to 
flood in freely. They competed with one another to provide global monopoly 
capital with the most incentives by keeping their wages low and working 
conditions flexible and by lowering taxes and imposing the least stringent 
environmental regulations. In the mid-1990s these incentives attracted large 
flows of foreign capital to Southeast Asian countries and littered these coun- 
tries with new factories that produced similar cheap products, like clothing, 
shoes, toys, electronics, etc. 

‘The capitalist propaganda machine declared that an economic miracle 
had arrived in Asia and that the 21% century would be the “Asian Century.” 
Then in 1997-98 a widespread economic crisis decimated these economies 
and almost all of the newly built factories were idled. Paul Krugman, a bour- 
geois Nobel Prize-winning economist, equated this economic crisis suffered 
by 660 million people in seven countries, which had produced a quarter 
of the world output, with the 1929 Great Depression in imperialist coun- 
tries.'? The crisis started in Southeast Asia and spread to Russia, South Korea, 
then to Brazil and beyond causing more suffering for additional hundreds 
of millions of people. The Latin American countries, which had suffered 
continuing crises since the 1980s plunged into deeper crisis extending from 
Argentina, Brazil, Mexico, to Uruguay, Paraguay, Bolivia, Columbia, and 
Peru. We are compelled to ask: if this is not barbarism, what is? 

We can no longer afford the kind of progress that comes from “planned 
obsolescence” or the waste and suffering brought by the capitalist business 
cycle. The amount of resources—fossil fuels, metals, plastic and minerals— 
required to make new products at a faster and faster rate dictated by the 
market and then disposing of them soon after they are made, as well as the 
destruction brought by repeated capitalist crises, is overwhelming the earth. 
As we carefully examine the last stage of capitalism we find a seemingly 
unstoppable monstrous system sweeping the world by unleashed global 
monopoly capital, ruthlessly ripping apart the people, land, and environ- 


"Paul Krugman, The Return of Depression Economics, WW. Norton & Co., 
1999. 


25 


From Victory to Defeat 


ment. Imperialism immensely benefited monopoly capital, but it is devas- 
tating the majority of the world’s population, exhausting its resources and 
destroying its natural environment. This kind of progress we do not want 
and cannot afford. We are facing a well-documented environmental crisis 
unprecedented in human history.'’ Capitalism, dictated by the will of capital 
for limitless expansion, is on a collision course with the limits of the planet 
where all of us reside. 

Socialism is the only kind of development that can stop the earth 
from destruction. During socialist construction in China the economy did 
not depend on the whims of the capital for production and investment deci- 
sions, and it did not suffer from the ups and downs of the business cycle. 
Decisions about new technology were not based on an obsession for market 
share but were made rationally by carefully considering all relevant factors, 
including conserving resources, concern for the environment and also for 
the value placed in the labor imbedded in producing machinery and equip- 
ment. While the capitalist market always drives businesses without the new- 
est technology out, socialist economy demonstrated that more enterprises 
with less advanced technology can coexist with those with more advanced 
technology as long as together they produce useful products for people. This 
is especially crucial for poor countries where capital is scarce and where for- 
eign competition based on superior technology has made domestic industri- 
alization almost impossible. Socialist development in China demonstrated 
that a less developed country can rely on its own resources and people to 
develop its economy. Development based on self-reliance was only possible 
with socialist development where the logic of capital no longer dominated." 

When state-owned industrial enterprises were phasing out commod- 
ity production, it was a fundamental and significant change toward the 
direction of communism. In that process each state-owned enterprise was 
considered part of the whole, and they were under a unified accounting 
system. Therefore, instead of competing with one another, different enter- 


5 The Global Commission on the Economy and Climate: https://newclimateecon- 
omy. report/2016/wp-content/uploads/sites/4/2014/08/NCE_2016Report.pdf 
UN Environment/Emissions Gap Report 2018: http://wedocs.unep.org/bitstream/ 
handle/20.500.11822/26895/EGR2018_FullReport_EN.pdf?sequence=1 &isAl- 
lowed=y Background document to the Global Sustainable Development Report 
2019 bya pour of UN-appointed “independent scientists”: https://bios.fi/bios-gov- 


ernance_of_ economic_transition.pdf 
4 See Question V. 


26 


Question II. (A) 


prises in a certain industry cooperated with one another. For example, a 
technologically advanced steel enterprise helped build a new steel enterprise 
by providing it with a plant design, machinery and equipment, and even 
technical personnel. Experienced engineers in the old steel plant went to 
the newly built plant to consult, and/or engineers in the new plants went to 
the more advanced plant for training. Since both the old plant and the new 
plant were parts of the same whole, the old plant did not consider the aid 
given to the new plant an “expense.” It was through cooperation that indus- 
trialization spread in socialist China from the East coast and the Northeast, 
where industrialization was more advanced, to the more remote regions in 
the North and Northwest. There was actually a catchy phrase to describe this 
phenomenon: “An old hen laying eggs all over the places’—meaning, in this 
example, that an older steel plant gave birth to dozens of new steel plants. It 
demonstrated that cooperation was far superior to competition. 


Phasing out labor power as a commodity 


During China’s socialist construction labor power was in the process 
of being phased out as a commodity, something that could be bought and 
sold. This is an equally important characteristic of socialism that is funda- 
mentally different from capitalism. The State established an eight-grade wage 
scale that it applied nationwide to all workers in state-owned enterprises. 
The wage scale was based on worker skills and years of service with some 
adjustments for cost-of-living differences in different parts of the country. 
Wages of engineers with college degrees were higher. But as time went on 
engineers’ wages were lowered if they had received their college education 
after 1949 when the State paid for their college education expenses plus 
living allowances." 

During the socialist construction state-owned enterprises received 
wage funds from the State to cover their total wage bill plus the cost of 
providing benefits to workers, which included low-rent housing, subsidized 
food and utilities, basically free medical care, education and other services. 
The transfer of wage funds from the State to workers via the enterprises 
removed the responsibility of cadres (in China, referred to as “ganbu,” lit- 
erally translated as “backbone personnel”) in charge of the enterprises, to 


5 All of the expenses of college education were paid by the State, including tuition, 


books, and room and board. Additionally students also received a monthly stipend 
for miscellaneous expenses. 


27 


From Victory to Defeat 


meet wage and benefit payments from the enterprise revenues. Managers in 
capitalist countries often lay off workers, reduce work hours, or cut worker 
benefits when the enterprise they manage fails to meet profit targets. Ganbu 
in state-owned enterprises had no such authority because the State guaran- 
teed workers’ jobs by transferring the wage fund to cover wages and benefits. 
Transferring the wage fund directly from the State to the workers via the 
enterprise was the only way to guarantee permanent employment and the 
amount of wages and benefits workers received. 

It is important to look at the completely different perspectives on 
workers’ wages and benefits in a capitalist society versus a socialist society. 
In a capitalist society the goal of production is to maximize profits. Profit 
in a capitalist enterprise is dependent on the surplus value extracted from 
workers so, therefore, the entire industrial organization is set up for pro- 
duction to run “efficiently” to increase workers’ surplus value. Higher wages 
and better benefits logically reduce the surplus value and serve as drags on 
profits, so they need to be kept as low as possible. On the other hand, in a 
socialist society one of the most important goals of production is to improve 
people’s material lives. Higher wages and better benefits are the very reasons 
to fulfill the purpose of production. In state-owned factories in addition to 
managing matters related to production, the cadres (ganbu) in charge of 
different departments also had the responsibility to oversee many aspects of 
workers’ lives including food, housing, utilities, nurseries and schools (from 
kindergarten sometimes all the way to high school), as well as recreation 
and organizing political study. Ganbu even served as counselors/social work- 
ers to resolve issues among family members and/or co-workers. In other 
words, ganbu paid great attention to all aspects of workers’ lives. If a ganbu 
neglected this part of his/her responsibility or failed to handle these matters 
fairly, he/she would be criticized. 

Whether labor power is or is not a commodity is of critical impor- 
tance. Marx spent the first volume of Capital explaining how the capitalist 
extracts surplus value from workers in the process of production. He ana- 
lyzed how surplus value was realized into profits when the product was sold. 
Marx explained how, unlike feudal society, exploitation takes place in capi- 
talist society during the process of production where the capitalist buys labor 
power as a commodity. Therefore, we can only end exploitation by ending 
the buying and selling of labor power as a commodity. Whether labor power 
is or is not a commodity necessarily dictates how the laborer is treated. In a 


28 


Question IT. (A) 


capitalist society when labor power is a commodity, the laborer can be hired 
and fired at any time. As far as the capitalist is concerned, his only interest is 
to buy the labor power when needed and to stop buying it when there is no 
longer the need. The capitalist has no concern for the laborer. In contrast, 
in socialist China a worker was guaranteed a job and livelihood including 
retirement and medical care. In socialist society where labor power ceased to 
be acommodity, laborers were treated as the creators of wealth, both for the 
factory and for the whole society. This was the most important reason why 
workers were so highly respected in socialist China. Nowhere in the world 
during any historical period were workers ever accorded such respect and 
dignity. 

Moreover, when labor power ceased to be a commodity the relation- 
ship between workers and machines changed fundamentally. Living labor 
commanded the machines (capital that contains dead labor) instead of the 
other way around. In the early days of capitalism the Luddites destroyed 
machines because they believed that machines were their enemies that could 
make their jobs obsolete. On capitalist assembly lines, production workers 
cheer when the line breaks down. During socialist construction in China, 
machines were not treated as the enemy; workers treated machines as valu- 
able tools that helped them in production. Workers were proud when they 
mastered skills of how to use machines properly to produce the best prod- 
ucts, paying great attention to maintaining machines, many going to check 
on the machines on their day off. (Workers lived in industrial complexes 
within walking distance to the factories.) 

Even though China’s development between 1956 and 1978 was social- 
ist, contradictions continued to exist within the industrial sector as well as 
between the economic base and the superstructure. When we say the state- 
owned industries were phasing out commodity production and phasing out 
labor power as a commodity, it did not mean the process of phasing out was 
completed. Actually the process to phase out commodity production and 
labor power as a commodity takes a very long time. Even so, within a short 
period of two decades from 1956 to 1978 we began to see how a socialist 
society operated qualitatively differently from a capitalist society. This will be 
further explored in the discussion about changes in the superstructure and 
the challenges China faced in developing socialism. 


29 


From Victory to Defeat 


Question II. (B) 


How did the relations of production change in the collectively owned 
agricultural sector? 


Toward the end of Land Reform two opposing views existed within 
the Chinese Communist Party on how to develop China’s agriculture. The 
debate between these opposing views reflected the fundamental differences 
between Mao Zedong and Liu Shaogi (and later Deng Xiaoping) on issues 
regarding how to develop a socialist economy. When the means of produc- 
tion in the industrial sector were transferred from the private sector to the 
State, members of the Chinese Communist Party were basically in agree- 
ment even though some members (basically Liu and his followers) thought 
the transfer should have proceeded more slowly. However, when it came 
to the development of the agricultural sector, the difference between Mao 
and Liu was sharp and substantive. As far as Liu was concerned, after Land 
Reform and the transfer of the means of production in the industrial sector 
to the State, the principal contradiction in China was between the “advanced 
social system” (meaning the relations of production) and the “backward 
social productive forces,” as clearly expressed in the Resolution of the Eighth 
National Congress of the CCP in 1956.'° Therefore, according to Liu (and 
later Deng), the main task of the CCP was to devote itself to the develop- 
ment of the productive forces. Mao, on the other hand, believed that the 
social system (the relations of production and the superstructure) was far 
from being advanced, and that contradictions still existed within the eco- 
nomic base as well as between the economic base and the superstructure.'” 
These philosophical differences between Mao and Liu caused them to view 
China’s socialist development from entirely different perspectives. 

Mao was a firm believer in Marxist dialectical materialism. He saw 
that in the contradiction between the productive forces and the relations of 
production, the productive forces are the principal aspect. In the contradic- 
tion between theory and practice, practice is the principal aspect; in the con- 
tradiction between the economic base and the superstructure, the economic 


'© “Resolution of the Eighth National Congress of the Communist Party of China,” Eighth 
National Congress of the Communist Party, 16. 


'7 Mao Zedong, On the Correct Handling of Contradictions Among the People, Selected 
Works of Mao Ise-tung, Vol. V, 394-395. 


30 


Question II. (B) 


base is the principal aspect. However, Mao also believed that under certain 
conditions, such aspects as the relations of production, theory and super- 
structure, could come to the fore to play the principal and decisive role. Mao 
explained that when people regard these respective positions (productive 
forces vs. relations of production, theory vs. practice, and economic base vs. 
superstructure) as fixed, instead of changeable in their respective positions, 
they hold a mechanical-materialist point of view, not a dialectical-materialist 
one. The mechanical-materialist believed that under no circumstances could 
the relations of production, theory, or superstructure become the dominant 
aspect of the contradiction. 

Mao did not hold the mechanical-materialist point of view; he 
believed that under certain conditions the productive forces and relations 
of production could exchange places and the relations of production could 
play the dominant role in making change. For example, when the relations 
of production remain unchanged for a long time, the productive forces can 
become stagnant and stop developing unless a change in the relations of 
production (such as a revolution) occurs. In that case the relations of pro- 
duction can play the principal and decisive role.'* Mao further explained 
that while it is true that in the contradiction between the superstructure 
and economic base the economic base is the principal aspect, under certain 
conditions the superstructure can become the principal aspect. During a rev- 
olution the relations of production are changed by people actively engaged 
in class struggle (political, ideological, and cultural struggle in the sphere of 
the superstructure), which can play the leading role in changing the relations 
of production. Dialectical-materialism was fundamental to Mao’s analysis of 
social change. It played the most important role in constructing his strategy 
to win the long revolutionary war and it also played the most important role 
in shaping his strategy on political and economic development during the 
socialist transition. 

In order for feudal ideology to lose its influence, its material base of 
feudal land tenure had to be destroyed. However, even when Land Reform 
ended the feudal land tenure system, Mao saw that feudal ideology had stay- 
ing power; if left unchallenged, it could easily lodge itself in the new eco- 
nomic base. Therefore, without careful ideological work to get rid of feudal 
ideology, it could prevent the new economic base from taking root. Mao 


8 Tbid., p. 336. 
31 


From Victory to Defeat 


regarded Land Reform not just as a way to redistribute land to the peasants, 
but also as a social movement to propagate new ideology, one that explained 
why exploitation was wrong and that it was unjust for landlords to forcefully 
take the product of the peasants’ labor. When the peasants adopted this 
new way of thinking they became determined and empowered to right past 
wrongs and were energized to complete Land Reform and engage in move- 
ments to collectivize agriculture. 

Land Reform in the newly liberated areas in China’s countryside from 
19491952 gave hundreds of millions of peasants a plot of their own land 
for the first time in their lives. Although land holdings averaged only 0.2 
hectares per capita, peasants cultivated their newly possessed land with great 
enthusiasm. The output of both grain and cotton went up rapidly between 
1949 and 1952. By 1953, however, grain production became stagnant and 
cotton production decreased." 

After one hundred years of destruction from wars and landlord neglect, 
China’s natural environment for agriculture was very fragile, and arable 
land was scarce and infertile. Agricultural infrastructure such as irrigation 
was in total ruin. Before Liberation, natural disasters such as drought and 
flood were widespread, and famine was a common occurrence. After Land 
Reform was completed in 1953, in addition to owning very small plots of 
poor quality land, the majority of peasants, more than 300 million, owned 
very few productive tools. Among the poor and lower-middle peasant house- 
holds—60 to 70% of China’s peasantry—many did not even own a plow, 
let alone other farm tools or draft animals. Without farm tools enthusiasm 
alone could not continue to increase production. Moreover, in 1953 and 
1954, floods and drought affected large areas of farmland. Individual peas- 
ants were defenseless against such natural disasters. Before Liberation, when 
natural disasters hit, many peasants were forced to migrate to neighboring 
provinces just to survive. After Land Reform, when the health conditions 
of almost all peasants were still very poor, families were often devastated by 
illness or the death of a family member. Some farm households were also 
without any productive labor when their loved ones sacrificed their lives 
during the war against Japan and/or the war against the Kuomintang. When 
peasant families faced any of these problems they had to borrow money. 
Facing debts at usurious interest rates, some peasants were forced to sell their 


'° See Su Xing, “The Two Line Struggle, Socialist vs. Capitalist, after the Land Reform,” 
Jing Jin Yan Jiu, (Research in Economics)1965, no. 7, p. 24. 


32 


Question II. (B) 


newly acquired land. Before the cooperative movement began, land sales and 
private borrowing had begun to rise, as had the number of peasants who 
hired themselves out as farm hands.”° 

Thus, although Land Reform resolved the principal contradiction 
between peasants and landlords, it could not solve the urgent need to increase 
production to improve the majority of peasants’ material conditions. The 
new situation proved small-scale subsistence farming was not a stable situa- 
tion or a viable solution for agricultural development. The farming situation 
in China at that time was very similar to the situation in many colonial and 
semi-colonial countries in the world today. It was obvious that agricultural 
production had to be modernized and the scale of production increased. 
In China after Land Reform the struggle surrounding agricultural develop- 
ment intensified. The main struggle was not whether agricultural production 
needed to increase in scale and be modernized—the struggle was over how 
to achieve it. In other words, mechanization versus collectivization: which 
should come first? Mao believed that peasants could be organized to join 
their small pieces of land together and share their limited productive tools 
to first increase agricultural output and then to make improvements in land 
and build infrastructure to prepare the land for mechanization and modern- 
ization. Liu Shaogi, on the other hand, believed that after Land Reform fur- 
ther changes in the relations of production were unnecessary and all efforts 
should be devoted to the development of productive forces. Liu believed that 
only when China could produce enough steel and acquire the technology 
to manufacture tractors and other agricultural machinery and equipment 
would the conditions exist for the modernization of agricultural production. 

With a mechanical-materialist perspective, productive forces are 
always the dominant aspect in the contradiction between productive forces 
and relations of production—the relations of production can never become 
the dominant aspect. From that point of view, that relationship is fixed, 
which is why Liu insisted that mechanization had to come first. Mao, on 
the other hand, believed that further changes in the relations of production, 
meaning collectivization, had become the principal aspect of the contradic- 
tion and that changing it would help develop productive forces. Mao saw the 
energy and the enthusiasm of the Chinese working people as the source for 
economic development. He recognized that when peasants were mobilized 


20 Tbid. 
33 


From Victory to Defeat 


and their consciousness raised to a higher level, they created the possibility 
of organizing production on a scale larger than a single farm-household. He 
saw that ideology (in the sphere of superstructure) could play a major role in 
changing the relations of production from privately owning and farming a 
small piece of land to collectivization. 

Mao won the first major debate within the Chinese Communist Party 
on how to develop China's agriculture. Collectivization began soon after 
Land Reform initially by organizing mutual-aid teams in production and 
then elementary co-ops and advanced co-ops, and finally the formation of 
communes in 1958. 

One of the most challenging problems in China’s agriculture histori- 
cally and currently is the lack of arable land. China has less than 9% of the 
world’s arable land, but it has to produce food and other agricultural prod- 
ucts for 22% of the world’s population. On a per capita land basis, its arable 
land is just over one mu or 0.0827 hectares (1 mu = 0.067 ha)—about one 
third of the world’s average. At the conclusion of the Chinese Revolutionary 
War, Western experts never expected that China would ever be able to feed 
its people. With such limited arable land, the only way to increase produc- 
tion was through intensive cultivation to increase the yield per cultivated 
area. Between 1952 and 1978 China was able to double crop yields per unit 
of arable land through the collectivization of agriculture. 

Collectivization of agriculture began at the conclusion of Land Reform. 
It started with mutual-aid teams. Several (20 or more) peasant households 
were organized to share their tools and labor in production. That proved not 
to be so difficult because when farm tools and labor were more fully utilized, 
output increased and every family benefited. 

The next step in agricultural collectivization was the formation of 
elementary cooperatives, where peasant households joined their land and 
productive tools together in farm production but still retained the owner- 
ship of their tools. That ownership entitled peasant households that owned 
them to claim shares of output in addition to the shares each household 
received according to the amount of the labor they contributed. At this stage 
of organizing it became more complicated, because the peasants’ decision 
to join or not to join depended on their potential gains. Mao saw that in 
order for the co-ops to be on solid ground, peasant participation had to be 
on a voluntary basis. The policy of the CCP was to encourage peasants to 
join the cooperatives but respect their decision to go it alone. The poor and 


34 


Question II. (B) 


lower-middle peasants (more than 65-70% of all peasants) who owned a 
small plot of land but owned very few farm tools, had little chance to make 
it on their own. They were the staunchest supporters of the co-ops. ‘The rich 
and some upper-middle peasants who had owned larger plots of land and a 
few farm tools could hire workers and increase production, so they opposed 
joining the co-ops. The middle peasants took a “wait and see” attitude to see 
how the co-ops fared. The co-ops increasing output to win over the middle 
peasants was critical to the success of the co-op movement. Eventually the 
middle peasants were won over and the rich peasants had no choice but to 
join, however reluctantly, because they could no longer hire anyone to work 
for them. 

Organizing peasants into cooperatives was not an easy task. For 
one thing peasants in China had never experienced working cooperatively 
together. Peasants did not know what it would be like. When the coopera- 
tive movements were spreading throughout the countryside there was great 
worry about whether the co-ops could increase production and whether the 
increases could be sustained. There were cases, though only a very small 
minority, where crop production decreased and organizing efforts failed. 
Credit for the co-op movement’s success has to be given to CCP policy to 
rely on the poor peasants and to win over the middle peasants. Credit should 
also be given to the majority of party cadres who had just finished fighting 
the war and knew next to nothing about organizing co-ops. But these cadres 
were mostly from the poor peasant families and they keenly understood their 
struggles and hopes for a better life. They trusted the Party based on what 
they witnessed during the revolutionary war and the land reform it imple- 
mented. They worked tirelessly and wholeheartedly to support the Party and 
successfully completed the collectivization of agriculture. 

After the elementary co-ops the next step was the formation of 
advanced co-ops. As William Hinton, well-known author of many books 
and articles about China’s land reform and collectivization, pointed out in 
Shenfan, when production began to increase after the formation of the ele- 
mentary co-ops, it became obvious that most of the increases were due to 
more intensive labor rather than the use of farm tools and implements.*! The 
majority of team members began to resent the fact that the tool owners con- 
tinued to draw larger amounts of the co-op’s rising income. ‘The issue of how 


*! William Hinton, Shenfan, The Continuing Revolution in a Chinese Village, Random 
House, 1983, 120-121. 


35 


From Victory to Defeat 


much in dividends should be paid to the owners of productive tools became 
more complex and divisive. The solution was to move forward to advanced 
cooperatives where the co-ops bought the productive tools from their own- 
ers with a onetime payment according to negotiated prices. This was how 
co-ops progressed from elementary level to advanced level. As their incomes 
increased the advanced cooperatives were able to buy more farm equipment 
with funds accumulated from their rising income. From that point on in 
China's countryside, income was distributed only according to the amount 
of labor each farm worker contributed; farm tools (capital) ceased to claim a 
share of the total income. 

The collectivization of agriculture was completed in 1958 with the 
formation of the communes. The communes had a three tier-ownership 
system: communes, production brigades, and production teams. In 1962 
production teams consisted of 15 to 30 farm households averaging 24.9 
families; production brigades, the size of a village, averaged 7.9 production 
teams; communes, the size of a county, averaged 9.4 production brigades. 
Each commune administered agricultural (and later industrial) production, 
commerce, education, social welfare, and self-defense (with its own militia). 
The communes also managed their own finances and were responsible for 
collecting and paying taxes to the State, an accumulation fund for invest- 
ment (seeds, new farm tools, and/or building infrastructure), and a welfare 
fund (medical care, education, care for the elderly and the needy) for all 
commune members.” 

As the productive forces developed, communes used their accumula- 
tion funds to build large-scale irrigation and drainage systems, roads, hos- 
pitals, and purchase large agricultural instruments. By the late 1960s rural 
industrialization began and communes also owned factories. Production 
brigades built and owned factories, large agricultural machinery, milling sta- 
tions, animal/poultry farms, sewing stations, and other facilities. Brigade 
members shared the use of these facilities. 

Production teams owned land and small agricultural instruments. 
Each team functioned as a basic accounting unit. Team members elected 
their team leader, who was in charge of production and distribution, but 
continued to do farm work with other team members. After paying taxes to 


2 The commune ens for its members’ medical expenses, so the out-of-pocket 


expenses for medical treatment for members were extremely low. Students only paid 
for their basic supplies like notebooks and pencils. 


36 


Question II. (B) 


the State (via the commune) they made payments to the commune for the 
accumulation and welfare funds. At harvest time the team distributed quota 
grain to its members based on age and the physical intensity of their labor. 
Then the rest of its income was distributed to team members according to 
the amount of work points each member earned during the year. One day 
of labor earned a minimum of about five work points to a maximum of ten, 
depending on the physical strength and skills required for the work. Team 
members’ attitude toward work, such as willingness to help others, was also 
figured in when the worth of one day’s work was assessed. The evaluation 
and assessment of work points each person earned for a day of work was 
discussed, debated, and determined democratically by all team members. 

With the exception of some very poor communes, most people’s lives 
in rural China improved dramatically. Each member of the production team 
received a quota of grain from his/her production team, even if he/she was 
too young, too old, or too sick to work. In addition to food grain, members 
received low cost health care and low cost education paid by the commune’s 
welfare fund, which also covered major expenses for needy families.” In 
addition the State allocated funds to pay for education (teacher salaries and 
school construction) in the rural areas, as well as the cost of training teachers 
and healthcare personnel who worked in the countryside. 

The formation of communes fundamentally transformed the relations 
of production in the agricultural sector. This fundamental change in the 
relations of production was the main reason for the rapid development of 
productive forces in China's agriculture. By joining the land together and 
combining their tools, China’s peasants were able to work collectively to 
improve the quality of the land and to build agricultural infrastructure. 
‘They were able to accumulate more funds to buy more and better tools and 
worked extremely hard to improve the fertility of the land. When chemi- 
cal fertilizer was not yet available they saved, preserved, transported, and 
applied animal and human waste to improve the soil. When peasants were 
not busy planning and harvesting, they worked together to prepare the land 
for mechanization by joining pieces of land together, flattening the land, fill- 
ing in the small creeks, and terracing the land in hilly areas. Large numbers 
of peasants were organized to work on land preservation and improvement 


°3 The five guarantees for the needy families (including ae who had lost their 
ability to work, or the elderly who had no children) were: food, clothing, shelter, 
medical, and burial. 


3/ 


From Victory to Defeat 


projects. These projects accelerated in the late 1960s and early 1970s when 
agricultural production was more stable and more labor could be diverted 
from farm work to construction. They also worked on land improvement 
and infrastructure construction projects during seasons when agricultural 
work was slack. As a result peasants in China extended their active working 
days from 119 a year in the 1950s to 250 a year in the 1970s.4 

Alexander Eckstein, an expert on Chinese economy, said the following 
about the farmland capital construction in his paper on “Zhe Chinese Devel- 
opment Model”: 

More concretely, it indeed means reshaping the geographical features 
of an area to provide the physical conditions necessary for the application 
of an appropriate mix of other inputs—labor, machinery, fertilizer, and 
improved seed strains—to bring about high and stable yields. This often 
requires squaring or terracing the land; at times it involves leveling moun- 
tains and transporting the soil manually in baskets for several kilometers 
to build a huge dam or to cover some areas with topsoil. In many areas, it 
means constructing underground drainage channels, reservoirs, canals, irri- 
gation channels, pumping stations, and tube wells.” 

In addition to all the fieldwork and capital construction, China’s agri- 
culture production organized under the commune also facilitated advance- 
ment in agricultural technology. When agricultural development was sta- 
bilized in the mid-1960s, rural industrialization began in earnest from the 
energy created during the Great Leap Forward. By the mid-1960s, along 
with growth in agricultural production, small-scale industries were set up 
by production brigades and communes in the countryside. (For details of 
achievements in China’s agriculture see Question VI. below.) 


*4 Nicholas R. Lardy, Economic Growth and Employment in China, Oxford University 
Press, 1979, 7-8. 


> Eckstein’s original footnote: “These major construction projects have been under 

way for some times. They could be observed during my visit to China in December 
. They were given a renewed impetus by the National Conference on Learnin 

1972. They gi d imp by the Now | Conf L 

from Taichai held in Sie! and October 1975 and were described in some detai 

in American Rural Small-Scale Industry Delegation, Rural Small-Scale Industry,” Chap- 

ter 5, pp. 2-5 and Chapter 6, p. 7. 


38 


Question III. 


Question III. 


How did the superstructure change from feudal and capitalist to so- 
cialist from 1949 to 1978, and how important was the Cultural Revo- 
lution to this change? 


Since exploitation exists both in feudal and capitalist society, there has 
to be a political structure that supports the exploitation and a correspond- 
ing cultural and value system that justifies it. China had a very long history 
of feudalism and thus feudal ideology ran deep, dominating how people 
thought and behaved. Even today remnants of feudal ideology remain. The 
1949 revolution turned Chinese society upside down and shook feudal ide- 
ology to its core. Land Reform followed by the collectivization of agriculture 
not only destroyed the feudal economic base, it also fundamentally chal- 
lenged the feudal ideology that justified a very privileged few forcibly taking 
the fruits of other people’s labor. It also challenged the oppressive patriarchal 
feudal culture, which rigidly assigned each person's place in society accord- 
ing to a pre-determined order. 

As stated in Question II. (A), as the State took over the industrial 
enterprises, it aimed to change the relations of production by phasing out 
commodity production and labor power as a commodity. Workers in state 
enterprises received wages and benefits directly from the State. While indus- 
trial workers in capitalist countries had to fight hard for the eight-hour work- 
day and for any increase in wages and improvement in working conditions, 
workers in state enterprises received them right away from the new govern- 
ment. In a society with such a long feudal past, the relationship between the 
workers and the Communist Party of China could not help but still have 
remnants of feudal ideology. Since workers in state enterprises all received 
the above-mentioned rights and benefits they, like other recipients of benev- 
olent endowments, were relatively content and passive. They were grateful to 
the Party and State for what they received and believed that working hard to 
build their country was in part a way to show their gratitude. This was espe- 
cially true for older workers who could compare the incredible differences 
between factory work before and after Liberation. Worker gratitude towards 
the Party and State extended to the cadres in charge of factory management, 
the overwhelming majority of whom, especially those at the higher levels, 
were communist party members. 


39 


From Victory to Defeat 


Revolutionizing Industrial Organization 


As stated earlier, one of the basic changes in the relations of produc- 
tion in state-owned industrial enterprises to phase out labor power as a com- 
modity would not have been possible had there not been a fundamental 
change in relationship between the cadres and the workers in the factories. 
Throughout China’s long history of feudalism, government officials always 
had absolute authority. This old and outdated ideology had staying power in 
the new society and could be easily manipulated by authority to reassert con- 
trol. After the transfer of ownership the cadres, who represented the State, 
had a lot of power and authority, and workers often did not question or chal- 
lenge them. The new cadres were certainly different from the old managers 
before Liberation; they, in many ways, went out of their way to look after 
the workers’ interests. However, despite the fact that workers (like peasants 
and other sectors of the masses) participated in the mass movements led 
by the Communist Party of China during the 1950s and early 1960s, their 
class-consciousness was not fully developed. Workers were not aware that 
changes in the relations of production were not guaranteed after the judicial 
transfer of ownership to the State, nor were they aware that political struggle 
continued at the highest levels within the Party—the outcome of which 
would determine the direction of the transition. Although it is true that even 
before the Cultural Revolution democracy in the workplace went far beyond 
that of factories in West because permanent employment status guaranteed 
workers their place in the factories, before the Cultural Revolution, workers 
did not seriously question or challenge the cadres’ authority in the factories. 

As industrial production increased and the number of industrial 
workers rose in the 1950s, work rules and production processes in factories 
became more rigid. The division of labor within the factories reflected the 
social division of labor in society as a whole. Graduates from universities 
and technical schools designed the products, developed the technology, and 
determined the labor process. Cadres managed the shops and made most 
decisions, which were seldom challenged by the workers. Mao saw that if 
this were to continue, a hierarchy of power would gradually take hold, pre- 
venting the production workers from eventually taking charge of running 
the factories. If workers could not be in charge of the factories how could 
they be expected to be in charge of the State? 

When workers of the Anshan Metallurgical Combine initiated changes 


40 


Question III. 


in the operation of their workplace in 1960, Mao took the opportunity to 
call on all factories to follow their new rules as guidelines for the operation of 
state enterprises. On March 22, 1960, he named these new rules the Angang 
Constitution. (Angang is the abbreviation for Anshang Steel and Iron.) 

The Angang Constitution consisted of five principles: (1) Put politics 
in command; (2) Strengthen party leadership; (3) Launch vigorous mass 
movements; (4) Systematically promote the participation of cadres in pro- 
duction labor and of workers in management, and (5) Reform any unrea- 
sonable rules and assure close cooperation among workers, cadres, and tech- 
nicians, and energetically promote technical innovation. 

Before the Cultural Revolution these guidelines did not receive enthu- 
siastic support from the workers. While workers enjoyed benefits endowed 
by the State, they did not see the two-line struggle being waged within 
the Party. As Mao advocated for more worker control in the state facto- 
ries, Liu Shaoqi advocated for Labor Reform to take away their permanent 
employment status. As early as the 1950s Liu Shaoqi began advocating for 
the labor-contract system. An essay from the recently published Labor Con- 
tract System Handbook reveals the history of Liu’s attempts to institute tem- 
porary contract workers in state-owned factories. The essay describes how, 
in 1956, Liu sent a team to the Soviet Union to study their labor system. 
Upon its return the team proposed the adoption of the labor-contract sys- 
tem modeled after the Soviet Union. However, when the changes were about 
to take place, the Great Leap Forward began, thus interrupting this model’s 
implementation. Then in the early 1960s, Liu again attempted to change 
permanent employment status by adopting a “two-track system”; enter- 
prises would employ more temporary and fewer permanent workers, and 
the mines would employ peasants as temporary workers. Then in 1965, the 
State Council announced a new regulation on the employment of tempo- 
rary workers, indicating that instead of permanent workers, more temporary 
workers should be hired. The regulation also gave individual enterprises the 
authority to use allocated wage funds to replace permanent workers with 
temporary workers. This time the Cultural Revolution interrupted Liu’s 
effort to reform the labor system, and in 1971 large numbers of temporary 
workers were given permanent status.”° 

After the Cultural Revolution began in 1966, and China’s population 


°6 “The History of Our Contract Labor System,” Labor Contract System Handbook, ed. 
Liu Chiang-tan, (Science Publisher, 1987): 1-18. 


4l 


From Victory to Defeat 


engaged in changing society, the principles of Angang were broadly propa- 
gated, widely discussed, and actually put into practice. To this day principles 
in the Angang Constitution are still some of the most radical guidelines 
to changing industrial organization and production processes in facto- 
ries.”” During the Cultural Revolution other important issues were debated, 
including material incentives and piece-wage rates. Through discussion and 
debate workers saw that using material incentive to induce competition 
among workers only divided the workers and damaged class unity. When 
factory rules and regulations were openly discussed and debated, workers 
realized more than ever that it was up to them to change the world they lived 
in. That high degree of industrial democracy was what Charles Bettelheim 
witnessed in China’s factories when he visited there in 1971. From what he 
observed in the factories and in society, Bettelheim wrote in the preface of 
his book: “Through discussions and struggles involving millions of workers 
and vast sections of the population, a new road was opened up in the strug- 


gle for socialism.””* 


Reforming the Education System 


Revolutionizing industrial organization in factories was one import- 
ant accomplishment of the Cultural Revolution. Reforming the education 
system was another. During the long history of feudalism, education was 
reserved for the very privileged few. A system of examinations evolved from 
this long history, designed as a way to select a few “qualified” intellectuals 
to join the ruling class. Landlord families paid tutors to educate their sons. 
‘The sons had to study hard and then take the difficult examination; if they 
passed, they could become officials serving in the imperial government. This 
system of selection was how the land-owning class linked to the ruling class. 
Education, as an avenue to advance in social stature, had deep roots in the 
thousands of years of feudalism and in the consciousness of ordinary people. 
‘The divide between mental work and physical work was similarly rooted. As 
Mencius famously said: “Those who work with their brain rule, and those 
who work with their muscles are ruled.” 

Modern Western-style education found its way into China in the 


7 A small group of people organized a commemoration of the 50" anniversary of the 
Angang Constitution in Beijing in March 2010. 


*8 Charles Bettelheim, Cultural Revolution and Industrial Organization in China, 
Monthly Review Press, 1974. 


42 


Question III. 


mid-1880s through missionary schools and later through returning students 
educated in the United States and other Western countries. Toward the end 
of the Qing Dynasty the first university was established and the examination 
system was abolished. After the 1911 revolution the government adopted 
many aspects of modern education from the West, including the levels of 
education and the number of years at each level: six years of elementary, 
three years of junior high, three years of high school, and four years of col- 
lege. Curriculum at different levels was changed to include modern science, 
modern languages, social sciences, psychology, and other subjects. In the 
1930s, however, only about 15% of Chinese children received elementary 
level education and even fewer attended high school. University education 
only served the extremely small ruling class in the urban areas and provided 
an important vehicle for obtaining wealth, fame and power. 

When the People’s Republic was established in 1949 the literacy rate 
was about 20%.” The focus of education in the early years of the new gov- 
ernment was to quickly increase the population’s literacy through formal 
schooling, as well as through literacy campaigns and establishing informal 
schools that taught people how to read and write. Between 1949 and 1965 
elementary school enrollment more than tripled from 45 million to 160 
million, secondary school enrollment increased 8.5 times from 2.3 million 
to 19.7 million, and college enrollment increased 4.3 times from 230,000 
to 930,000.” Curriculum at different levels went through major revisions; 
Western influence was largely replaced by Soviet influence. Education in 
urban areas was basically free of charge. College students no longer had 
to pay tuition and were also given monthly stipends to cover their living 
expenses. In this sense, education was no longer limited to those who could 
afford to pay and was expanded to include young people from other seg- 
ments of society. 

The basic philosophy of education, however, remained largely 
unchanged and continued to follow in the old tradition. Although schools 
expanded at all levels during the first 16 years of the new republic, there 
was a strong bias in favor of the urban population at the expense of the 
2% The criteria of literacy varied from knowing 1,500 Chinese characters to know- 
ing over 3,000 or more characters. For more details, see Dwight Perkins and Sjajid 


Yusuf, Rural Development in China, The John Hopkins University Press, 1984, chap- 
ter 8. 


°° State Statistical Bureau, Statistical Yearbook of China, 1981 (Hong Kong Economic 
Information Agency, 1982) 


43 


From Victory to Defeat 


rural. Even in urban areas, children of worker families were at a disadvan- 
tage, although cost was no longer a barrier for them to attend school. In the 
1950s and 1960s, schools at different levels used test scores to judge student 
performances, and admission to high school and college was based on the 
entrance examination scores. “Key schools” were set up to attract students 
with the best scores and a tracking system within them—very much like the 
tracking system in US schools—further differentiated their futures; place- 
ment in the upper tracks of “key high schools” almost guaranteed a place in 
the best universities by enabling them to achieve high scores on the entrance 
examination. The “key schools” had more resources, better trained teachers, 
and better facilities.*! This system of competition based on book learning 
strongly favored students from intellectual families, which had more books 
and parents who were better equipped to help their kids raise their exam 
scores. While children from worker families were at a disadvantage, children 
of peasant families had even more limited chances to attend high school; all 
the barriers to enter university were almost insurmountable. Both feudalism 
and capitalism use the surplus created by workers and peasants to educate 
elites who turn around to rule them. If socialism continued that familiar 
pattern, where would future leaders of the working class come from? 

‘The admissions process and standards no longer met the needs of the 
new society, and neither did the curriculum. There was too much book learn- 
ing, which often imparted outdated and irrelevant knowledge that did not 
meet the urgent needs of China’s rapid industrial and agricultural develop- 
ment. Even though Mao was well versed in the ancient forms of the Chinese 
language, he always thought education in its traditional form stifled young 
people’s curiosity and imagination and provided no useful knowledge. He 
had dropped out of school a few times in his youth and studied on his 
own to acquire a wealth of knowledge in breadth and depth unmatched by 
known scholars. Thus Mao had a bias against the kind of formal education 
taught in regular institutions and saw education reform as a key to the suc- 
cess of building a new socialist society—not only so that young people could 
acquire useful knowledge for developing the economy, but also to bridge 
the divide between mental and physical work. However, in the institutes of 
higher learning, school administrations and faculties considered curriculum 
matters their prerogative—a role that was not to be challenged by anyone. 


31 Perkins and Yusuf, Ibid. 
44 


Question III. 


During the Cultural Revolution several basic questions confronted 
education reform. First, who should be admitted to schools of higher learn- 
ing? Second, what should be taught in these schools and how should book 
learning be connected to practice? And third, how could education be 
expanded to include more young people in the countryside? There was also 
the question of learning beyond classrooms and whether the length of for- 
mal education at different levels should be shortened. 

Education reform generated great enthusiasm among young Red 
Guards during the Cultural Revolution. Schools were suspended so that the 
young people could play a critical role in changing the education system.** 
Education reform provoked an uproar in institutions of higher learning. 
After three years of intense struggle, admission processes and standards 
were changed and written entrance examinations were abolished. After high 
school graduation, young people worked in either factories or on farms, and 
their work units decided who should be sent to school for further study. 
Additionally, large numbers of high school graduates in cities were sent to 
the countryside to learn how to work and learn from working in produc- 
tion. Curriculums were revised to better fit the needs of society. Physical 
labor was incorporated into the curriculum as an integral part of learning. 
University faculty in science and engineering started going to factories to see 
how to make a better connection between what they were teaching and what 
was needed for industrial development, while faculty in agricultural sciences 
went to the communes to help peasants improve planting methods and soil 
conditions, develop new seeds, and control pests. 

Despite the continuous lies told by the capitalist reformers about 
the “ten year loss” in China’s higher education, there were very significant 
achievements in both science and technology. These achievements laid the 
foundation for further development in the post-socialist years. More impor- 
tantly, education reform during the Cultural Revolution disseminated scien- 
tific knowledge to the broad masses of people—the workers and the peas- 
ants. 

The American Rural Small-Scale Industry Delegation that visited Chi- 
na’s small-scale rural industries in 1972 witnessed the confidence and pride 
of the peasant-workers who mastered the technology of machine making in 
their workshops. In Chapter X: "Expanding Knowledge and Attitude," the 


2 Schools were suspended for three years from 1966 to 1968. 
45 


From Victory to Defeat 


delegation report included the following, about the meaning of being “red 
and expert”: 


[In the stereotype] the experts want large-scale urban enterpris- 
es, full of the most advanced technology and imported machin- 
ery. The perfect “red” is, of course, the antithesis of this: one 
with the masses, confident in their ability and their methods, 
unintimidated by the presumed superiority of the technological 
mandarins and their foreign mentors... 


Central to the resolution of this contradiction is technological assim- 
ilation and accessibility: technologies which are felt to belong naturally to 
one’s immediate environment, not as wonderful and exotic phenomena; and 
technologies which are capable of being thoroughly understood and mas- 
tered by those at all levels who work with them. “Most of the machinery in 
this plant was made and installed by ourselves.” “Our own staff, in teams 
made up of old workers, cadres, and technicians, has produced 104 innova- 
tions in the past six months.” Such phrases, which we heard over and over 
again, bespeak an important role in assimilation and accessibility for local 
small-scale industry.* 

What this delegation witnessed in the workshops of rural small indus- 
tries speaks to the essence of education reform during the Cultural Revolu- 
tion and its short-lived success. 


Propagating Proletarian Art and Culture 


Related to education reform, changes were made in the areas of art 
and culture, including literature, music, film, and theater. Before the Cul- 
tural Revolution, mainstream theater and art rarely reflected the lives and 
work of workers and peasants. Traditional Chinese opera continued to tell 
the stories of old imperial dynasties, which had little relevance to the new 
society; a familiar subject of traditional Chinese brush paintings was an old 
man sitting idly in a boat appreciating the mystic mountains, as well as 
brush paintings of flowers and birds. It was obvious that basic changes in 
arts and culture were necessary when workers, peasants, and revolution- 


33 “The American Rural Small-scale Industry Delegation,” edited by ee Perkins, 
Rural Small Industry in the Peoples Republic of China, University of California Press, 
1977, 237-238. 


46 


Question III. 


ary soldiers were the main actors in the new society. Drastic changes in all 
areas of art and culture took place during the Cultural Revolution. A new 
breed of worker and peasant artists painted vivid pictures of their lives— 
proudly working with shiny new machines in factories and happily working 
in the fields with families during the harvest. The joy in these paintings was 
expressed in bold strokes and bright colors in contrast to the old paintings of 
the lonely old man created with a delicate stroke and muted colors. 

Many people today know about the eight famous Cultural Revolu- 
tion dramas portraying revolutionary heroes and heroines. Jiang Qing was 
responsible for the creation of these dramas on stage and in films, creatively 
applying traditional and contemporary art forms including Chinese opera 
and Western ballet to tell revolutionary stories. There were also many differ- 
ent forms of music explored and developed during this period. One of the 
most inspiring endeavors was encouraging music and art students to travel to 
national minority areas to record their music and art. The Chinese Commu- 
nist Party was very critical of the persistence of Han chauvinism. Since the 
great majority of dozens of Chinese ethnic groups were (are) Han, with few 
exceptions, historically the Han dominated China politically, economically 
and culturally. The CCP made friends with many national minorities during 
the Long March and after Liberation its policy toward national minorities 
was the most advanced in the world. After Liberation national minorities 
were given many political and economic privileges that the Han did not 
have. During the Cultural Revolution many efforts were made to preserve 
languages, arts, music, and other cultural aspects of national minorities. The 
CCP’s policies toward national minorities were the reason for peace between 
the Han and other minorities during the socialist period.** 


Promoting Democracy, the Spirit of Cooperation and Class Unity 


Another crucial achievement of the Cultural Revolution was the prac- 
tice of democracy at the grassroots level. The mere suggestion of democracy 
under socialism in China can cause controversy. Many people ask, “How 
could China have democracy, when it was under the one-party rule of the 
Communist Party?” If examined from a different perspective, however, a 


4 Through the long history of China, the ethnic majority Han Chinese oppressed 
national minorities. After Liberation, the central government deliberately compen- 
sated China’s national minorities, setting strict regulations to prevent the Han from 
their previous unfair practices. 


47 


From Victory to Defeat 


different picture with different questions emerges. As explained above, there 
were actually two headquarters within the Chinese Communist Party— 
the bourgeois headquarters that was actively pursuing capitalism, and the 
proletarian headquarters that was actively pursuing socialism. The division 
between the two headquarters became clearer after the 1950s. As time went 
on the struggle between them became more intense, when Mao saw that the 
contradictions could no longer be dealt with as contradictions among the 
people. 

The dichotomy between the two headquarters could not be resolved 
by a voting system like the bourgeois democracy of modern capitalism, 
which has a two-party or multi-party system with one or more Left-of-center 
parties and one or more Right-of-center parties. The differences between or 
among these political parties in the West are very limited in scope, because 
all of them have the goal of maintaining bourgeois rule. Some advocate more 
government involvement in managing the domestic economy and others 
prefer less, but their class interests are the same. Moreover, the range of for- 
eign policy alternatives is rather narrow, focusing mostly on options of the 
ruling class in imperialist countries. 

During the Cultural Revolution the issues between the two head- 
quarters were fundamental: between capitalism and socialism. The prole- 
tarian headquarters was for socialism and was not afraid of the masses—it 
encouraged their participation in the debate. A ruling party encouraging 
mass participation in discussing such fundamental issues was historically 
unprecedented. During the Cultural Revolution the masses practiced the 
four da’s: damin (big voice), dafang (big openness), dabianlun (big debate), 
and dazibao (big-character posters) to exercise grassroots democracy. The 
government could not censor what people wanted to say, because they sim- 
ply wrote big-character posters and pasted them on walls in the streets or 
hung them from ceilings in factories, schools or offices. The right for people 
to practice the four da’s as well as the workers’ right to strike were writ- 
ten into the constitution in 1975 (Articles 13 and 28). This demonstrated 
how the proletarian headquarters stood firmly on the side of the workers 
and masses. These same rights were quickly eliminated in 1978 as soon as 
the capitalist reformers seized power, and they were all formally dropped 
from the constitution in 1982. This shows how the bourgeois headquarters 
was afraid of the workers and masses by immediately eliminating their basic 
rights immediately after it seized power. 


48 


Question III. 


The Cultural Revolution not only articulated the major differences 
between socialism and capitalism, it took concrete steps in advancing social- 
ism in many spheres in Chinese society, demonstrating why the proletariat 
had to be in control in order to advance socialism. When the bourgeoi- 
sie seized power in 1977 it was able to reverse the course of development 
and dismantle the achievements made during the socialist period. It also 
distorted that period of history—especially the Cultural Revolution—and 
demonized Mao. However, the Cultural Revolution made it impossible in 
the long run for the bourgeoisie to keep up appearances that they were actu- 
ally pursuing socialism. Chinese workers and peasants lived and struggled 
through socialism and capitalism as two distinctively different societies, and 
their struggles during the past 40 years of capitalist reform have enabled 
them to have a better and deeper understanding of the meaning of the two- 
line struggle in many spheres of society and the crucial issues hotly debated 
during the Cultural Revolution. 

Toward the end of the Cultural Revolution the spirit of Dazhai and 
Daqing swept across the country. Under Chen Yonggui’s leadership, peasants 
in Dazhai worked long hours without rest in bitter weather, overcoming 
severe natural conditions to become self-reliant. They proved that men and 
women working together could move mountains. Their spirit inspired the 
whole country, and in the 1970s as many as 80 million peasants participated 
in “farmland capital construction” work each year, totaling the equivalent of 
eight billion labor days in land work. As a result, Chinese peasants changed 
the landscape of China’s countryside. They also worked cooperatively in 
conducting extensive and intensive scientific experiments to improve seed 
strains, soil conditions, and other farming methods. 

In Daqing, when workers realized that oil was an important source of 
energy in China’s industrialization, they devoted themselves to making inno- 
vations in order to increase oil production, many risking their lives drilling 
oil wells. Workers and peasants in China proved to themselves and to the 
world their capability to organize production and look beyond their own 
narrow self-interest. What they accomplished should have forever dispelled 
the myth that “Chinese people were nothing but a pile of loose sand” and 
that “workers and peasants were stupid, ignorant, and backward.” Yet Deng 
and his supporters insulted them by calling them lazy, because they “ate from 
a big pot,” and because they were “holding an iron rice bowl”—in reference 
to the guaranteed economic benefits for the masses in the socialist economy. 


49 


From Victory to Defeat 


‘The concrete experiences of China showed that socialist value has to 
be grounded in the socialist economic base. Question II. (A) and II. (B) 
explained changes in the economic base and this question explained changes 
in the superstructure. Fundamental changes in both the economic base and 
the superstructure made China a socialist country during the period between 


1956 and 1978. 


50 


Question IV. 


Question IV. 


What were some additional achievements made during China’s social- 
ist development? 


China achieved significant development in productive forces in all 
sectors of the economy. By relying on its own internal finances and indepen- 
dent technological advances, China was able to develop rapidly during the 
thirty years before 1978. (See Question V.) China’s socialist development 
built a strong industrial base and laid the foundation for its agriculture, 
vastly improving the material well-being of hundreds of millions of Chinese 
people. It was able to develop sophisticated technology in its industrial sec- 
tor and raise the level of mechanization in its agricultural sector. Between 
1952 and 1978 the annual growth rate for agriculture, industry, and trans- 
port and construction averaged 3.4%, 9.4% and 10.7% respectively. 


Achievements in Education and Health 


Before Liberation China was an extremely poor and backward coun- 
try. After 100 years of repeated foreign invasions and wars China’s economy 
was in ruins. Before 1949, malnutrition and outbreaks of infectious disease 
were the main reasons for China’s high death rate. During the 1930s China’s 
crude death rate was 27 per 1,000. The infant mortality rate was 156 per 
1,000 births for the country as a whole and was as high as 200 per 1,000 for 
the peasant population. On average, one third of all children died before the 
age of five. For the peasant population, life expectancy at birth was less than 
30 years.*’ These grim statistics are not surprising, considering that in 1949 
only one hospital bed existed for every 24,000 rural residents, and there was 
no preventive medicine to speak of.*° China was known worldwide as the 
“sick man of Asia.” 

After the collectivization of agriculture, grain and other agricultural 
products increased steadily, with the exception of 1959-1961. While people's 
diet improved, China made rapid progress in other areas to improve people’s 
health. Infectious diseases were eradicated by relying on the masses. Mobile 


35 Perkins and Yusuf, 133-134. 
36 Important Statistics on China’s Agriculture, Chinese Statistics Bureau, 1983, 13 & 


51 


From Victory to Defeat 


medical units toured the countryside and the cities explaining the causes 
of diseases and convinced people to change their sanitary conditions and 
personal hygiene practices in order to prevent them. Many mass campaigns 
were initiated to eradicate different diseases, along with mass campaigns to 
kill flies, mosquitoes, and other carriers of disease. People’s enthusiastic par- 
ticipation in these campaigns showed that they wanted to take charge of 
changing their own conditions. In only one and a half decades after the Lib- 
eration, China was able to eradicate most of the infectious diseases that had 
plagued its population for centuries, including cholera, diphtheria, tubercu- 
losis, schistosomiasis (snail fever), typhoid fever, smallpox, and many others. 

By the end of the 1970s even the World Bank reported that, despite 
China’s low per capita GNP, its death rate had dropped to the level of devel- 
oped countries. China’s crude death dropped from 27 per 1,000 in the 
1930s, to six per 1,000 in 1979, and during the same period its infant mor- 
tality rate dropped from 156 per 1,000 births to 56. Life expectancy at birth 
doubled within one generation.*’ In the 1940s about 80% of the Chinese 
population was illiterate. The Chinese Communist Party launched a liter- 
acy campaign in the Liberated Areas even before 1949. After Liberation the 
campaign proceeded at full speed. In the meantime, the number of schools 
expanded rapidly and by the mid-1960s about 70% of all primary school- 
aged children and 16% in the secondary school-aged group were enrolled 
in schools.** China’s accomplishment in health and education far exceeded 
advanced capitalist countries in their early stage of industrialization because 
China’s socialist development made satisfying human needs, instead of 
expanded capital accumulation, the goal of its development. 


Achievements in the Modernization of Agricultural Production (Social- 
ist Approach to Developing Science and Technology) 


After the commune system was established, the communes and bri- 
gades set up as many as 40,000 agricultural technological expansion and 
improvement stations with the help of the central government.” A four- 
level research network (county, commune, brigade, and team) covered the 
breadth of rural areas, greatly raising the level of technology for agricultural 


37 Perkins and Yusuf, 125-127;133-134; and Sidel & Sidel, 92-93. 
38 Sidel and Sidel, Ibid. 


» ‘These stations operated at the county, the commune, the brigade and the team 
levels. 


52 


Question IV. 


production by improving seed strains, controlling plant diseases and the use 
of both organic and chemical fertilizers to improve soil conditions towards 
increased production.*” According to Thomas B. Wiens, an agricultural 
specialist, China’s work on hybridization in the early 1950s achieved great 
results in new dwarf rice varieties and hybrid maize. Wiens explained how 
the seed selecting system of this research network was able to achieve the 
period from breeding to full-scale production in the shortest time possible.*! 
This demonstrated the superiority of having a network structure under the 
commune over commercial for-profit seed companies to improve agricul- 
tural technology. 

The Great Leap Forward in 1958-59 aroused peasant enthusiasm to 
industrialize the countryside. By the mid-1960s, when agricultural produc- 
tion was stabilized, small-scale industries were set up by production bri- 
gades and communes. These small industries produced tractors and other 
agricultural machinery and provided repair and maintenance services for 
increasingly mechanized agricultural production. They also produced other 
industrial goods such as fertilizer for farming and cement for construction, 
as well as consumer goods for rural residents. In 1975 Dwight Perkins, a 
specialist in international development and in Chinese studies, led a group 
of American delegates in different fields of study to visit small industries 
in China. They produced a comprehensive report on what they saw called 
Rural Small-Scale Industry in the Peoples Republic of China.” Their report 
gave a positive evaluation of the concrete conditions of these small-scale 
industries (which employed from under 50 workers to around 600 workers) 
and their impact. In the conclusion the group credited these small-scale rural 
industries that produced cement, fertilizer, electric power, and agricultural 


“© Wiens, Thomas B., “Zhe Evolution of Policies and Capabilities in China's Agricultural 
Technology,” Chinese Economy Post-Mao, A ee Monae of ae submitted to the 
Joint Economic Committee Congress of the United States, Volume 1. Policy and 
Performance, November 9, 1979, 671-703. 


41 Wiens said, “The extraordinary speed with which hybrid rice went from breeding 
to full-scale production is the most spectacular example yet of a facility which gives 
China several years’ edge over other countries in the rapidity with which plant breed- 
ing results can be app ied.” He continued, “Through the creation of the four-level 
research network, China has evolved a system permitting simultaneous stabilization, 
selection for local adaptability, evaluation, and seed multiplication in the shortest 
possible time.” 


® Perkins, Dwight, ed. Rural Small-Scale Industry in the Peoples Republic of China, 
1977, 56-58. 110-116. 


53 


From Victory to Defeat 


machinery with the rapid increase in the rates of investment and transfor- 
mation of Chinese agriculture. The report also credited the small-scale rural 
industries with raising the level of technical know-how in China’s country- 
side. Additionally the small-scale rural industries limited the pace of urban- 
ization and facilitated “the desire to reduce the social and economic status 
difference between urban and rural, industrial and agricultural sectors; the 
desire for greater popular participation and initiatives in the development 
process; and the desire to spread technical capabilities throughout the rural 
population.”* As a rule they did not use the most advanced technology, but 
they served the increasingly modernized agricultural sector well by using 
the level of technology available to them—often machinery and equipment 
phased out by industries in the state sector. 

The economic policies based on the worker-peasant alliance strength- 
ened the link between the industrial and agricultural sector. As the industrial 
sector developed, it supplied the agricultural sector with more and more 
industrial products, agricultural machinery, equipment, electric genera- 
tors, and chemical fertilizer. The three-tiered ownership of the commune 
mobilized and organized peasants to engage in extensive work to improve 
the land and infrastructure in China’s vast countryside. This extensive land 
work made the modernization of agriculture possible. Moreover, the small 
industries in rural areas made it possible to maintain and sustain the new 
modernized agriculture. These accomplishments can be summarized in the 
table below: 


® bid. 
54 


Modernization of Agriculture 


Question IV. 



































1952 1957 1965 1979 
Tractor-plowed area as a per- 0.1 a 15.0 42.4 
centage of cultivated area 
Irrigation area as a percentage 18.5 24.4 31.9 45.2 
of cultivated area 
Power irrigated as a percent- 
age of the total irrigated area be a4 aie ae 
Kilos of chemical fertilizer 0.7 33 18.7 109.2 
applied per hectare 
i aaa stations in 98 544 oe 83,224 
Generating capacity in thou- 
sands of kilowatts : ot ees 2702 
Total horsepower of agricul- 
tural machinery (10,000 hp) 23 i 1s ni ale 
Large and medium-size trac- 
tors (in thousands) fe Wed ES ge 
Small and walking tractors* 
Gathouende) na. na. 4 1,671 
Motors for agricultural drain- 
age Ac tention (10,000 i) 12.8 56.4 907.4 PollYPoll 
Combine harvesters 284 1,789 6,704 26,265 
Motor fishing boats n.a. 1,485 7,789 S225) 

















*Although these were intended for agricultural use, many were used for transporting 


goods. 


Source: Statistical Year Book of China, 1983, pp. 186, 197; and 1981 China Economic 


Yearbook, VI (in Chinese), p. 13. 


China’s socialist development was an astounding success. In merely 


twenty years Chinese workers, peasants, and intellectuals under party leader- 


ship not only built a solid foundation for China’s industries and agriculture 


and paved the way for further development, they also immensely improved 


the standard of living for a large and growing population. For the first time 


55 


From Victory to Defeat 


in China’s long history the working people had their basic needs—food, 
clean water, healthcare, education, and adequate housing—met and were 
credited with being the creators of wealth. They received the highest respect 
and dignity in the history of humankind. Again, how can anyone say that 
socialism in China failed? 


The Great Leap Forward for Women—Holding Up Half the Sky 


Under party leadership, Chinas workers and peasants together 
changed the world around them, turned the old feudal order on its head. 
In the process they also transformed themselves and their relationship with 
nature and with one another, including gender relationships between men 
and women. Moreover, the CCP consciously and consistently pushed poli- 
cies and sustained efforts aimed at equality between women and men. ‘This 
was based on the firm belief that a society could not be liberated from the 
shackles of old ideas and old practices without the liberation of women. In 
other words, in a new socialist society, women’s emancipation must proceed 
together with continuing class struggle for full emancipation from all forms 
of oppression. 

‘The massive campaign to eradicate illiteracy meant setting up classes 
in the countryside and cities and teaching ordinary peasants and workers 
to read and write. These literacy classes were especially instrumental to the 
liberation of women because, once women learned to read and write, they 
started reading newspapers, documents, and other printed matter, sharing 
information among themselves and communicating with the outside world. 
Their surroundings expanded from a narrow focus on their own families to a 
broader perspective that included their communities, the nation as a whole 
and even the world. Classes organized to eradicate illiteracy later evolved 
into political study groups, where they learned and discussed national and 
international news and debated government policies. 

As described above, the health of people improved dramatically from a 
better diet, health care, and personal hygiene. This benefitted the population 
in general and women in particular, because women had suffered dispropor- 
tionally from health issues due to diseases related to childbirth and had been 
the caretakers for sick family members. 

In the 1950s, as China’s industrialization took off and factories in 
both heavy and light industries sprouted up, both male and female industrial 


56 


Question IV. 


workers grew in number, and their status rose. In urban areas where most 
factories were state-owned, both male and female workers received adequate 
wages, equal pay for equal work, and lifelong job and benefit guarantees 
from the State. Although wages of factory workers were not high, their cost 
of living was kept low due to housing and utilities subsidies and free medical 
care for workers with a small monthly payment to cover their families. The 
workplace also provided free childcare. Moreover, women workers received 
additional benefits including being assigned lighter work during pregnancy, 
56 days paid maternity leave, and longer breaks for new mothers to nurse 
their newborns in nearby nurseries. Workers also had the option to eat in the 
factory canteens, which only charged for the cost of food but not the cost of 
meal preparations, liberating women from the domestic work in their kitch- 
ens. Women workers retired at the age of 50 and men retired at the age of 55 
with pensions that equaled 70% of their wages plus full benefits. 

After Land Reform, the collectivization of agriculture in the mid- 
1950s was another important step forward in raising the status of women. 
During the stage of advanced cooperatives, all land and other productive 
tools were collectively owned by the cooperatives. Individual households no 
longer had control over the means of production. At the same time, women 
began to earn work points from participating in production. As a result, 
the material base for patriarchy (male domination), a persistent legacy of 
many centuries of feudalism, gradually disappeared. After the communes 
were formed, work points women earned were recorded in their own names 
instead of the names of their families. This meant that women were treated 
as individual workers in the production teams and they—not their fam- 
ilies—received the cash or grain they earned from the accumulated work 
points. That was the first time peasant women could show the worth of their 
productive work. With the cash and grain they took home, their status in 
their families rose almost immediately. 

During the stage of elementary co-op in Xigou, a small village in 
Shanxi Province, a woman co-op leader, Shen Jilan, found a way to moti- 
vate women in the village to join production. Shen saw the importance of 
women in the drive to increase production; because in Xigou there were 
22 male productive members and 24 potential female productive mem- 
bers. Female members were reluctant to join production because the work 
points they earned had been recorded in their husbands’ names. Shen per- 
suaded them to join production by making a change so the work points they 


57 


From Victory to Defeat 


earned would be recorded in their own names. Soon they joined and formed 
an all-women team. These women showed tremendous enthusiasm and 
produced impressive amounts of output. Later Shen persuaded the party 
leader to send the women’s team to learn new skills. Upon their return, the 
all-women’s team produced as much output as the men’s team. Shen then 
led them to struggle for equal pay for equal work and won. They became 
the first to receive the same number of work points for a day’s work as that 
of men.“ Not many women received the same work points as men because 
more points were given to a day’s work that required heavier physical labor 
traditionally assigned to men. However, gradually, when machines began 
to replace human labor, the required physical strength to perform different 
tasks became less important, thus helping narrow the gap in work points 
between men and women. 


“4 See “The age et Status of Chinese Peasant Women,” Addendum to Chapter XII, 


Pao-yu Ching, Revolution and Counterrevolution, Chinas Continuing Class Struggle 
Since Liberation, Institute of Political Economy, Manila, 2012, 251-260. 


58 


Question V. 


Question V. 


What was China’s socialist development strategy? How was China’s 
socialist development different from colonial and semi-colonial coun- 
tries pursuing capitalist development? 


When compared with the experiences of countless other colonial and 
semi-colonial countries, socialist China was able to successfully develop its 
economy where others failed. The most important reason for China’s suc- 
cess was that it went through a socialist revolution and pursued socialist 
development under the leadership of the Chinese Communist Party. China’s 
socialist development made it possible for it to be independent from the 
interference and exploitation of imperialist countries. The CCP under Mao 
Zedong built a strong alliance between workers and peasants and adopted a 
self-reliant development strategy based on this alliance. 

Today in most colonial and semi-colonial countries, agriculture can no 
longer sustain the rural population, so peasants leave the land and migrate 
to nearby cities. In cities independent industrialization has failed and export 
manufacturing provides some low-wage jobs, but unemployment and pov- 
erty persist in most countries. Peasants who migrate from the countryside 
often live in deplorable conditions with no clean water, basic food, or medi- 
cal care and extremely poor sanitary conditions. Children living in the slums 
receive no education and often resort to rummaging through garbage dumps 
to find a few items to sell or some scraps of food to eat. We need to ask why 
the differences between the lives of workers and peasants in socialist China 
and those in colonial and semi-colonial countries are so stark. This section 
strives to provide some answers. 

The most distinguishing character of China’s socialist development 
was that it eliminated exploitation both internally and externally. All societies 
since the end of primitive communism have produced surplus, which is the 
amount of products produced above a given society's current consumption. 
Historically, surplus produced by society was used to build religious temples, 
palaces for kings and queens while they lived, and fancy mausoleums after 
they died. Surplus also was and is used for military conquest and to support 
the luxurious lives of the rich and powerful. Under feudalism surplus took 
the form of in-kind rent payment. Under capitalism surplus has taken the 
form of profit for capitalists who can use it for expanded capital accumula- 


59 


From Victory to Defeat 


tion, for military expansion and to pay for their material comforts. Surplus 
also takes the form of interest and rent. All forms of exploitation squeeze 
surplus from the working masses. Under capitalism it is the capitalists’ pre- 
rogative to decide whether to use the surplus for further capital expansion or 
for extravagant consumption. The working people who produce the surplus 
have no right to say how surplus is to be used. When a socialist country 
eliminates exploitation, surplus can then be invested in producing useful 
products and services for the working people. 

China had no internal exploitation because socialism eliminated the 
payment of profit, rent, and interest. This was possible because the state 
sector phased out commodity production and labor power as a commod- 
ity. In the collective sector after the formation of advanced co-ops, capital 
(farm tools) ceased drawing shares from total output. Moreover, in both the 
state sector and the collective sector great efforts were made to avoid layers 
of bureaucracy doing only administrative and non-productive work. Once 
exploitation was eliminated, all the surplus produced in the society could 
be invested in machinery and equipment to improve the land and to build 
infrastructure in order to expand future production. Equally important, in 
socialist China surplus was not squeezed excessively from the workers and 
peasants, so that significant improvements were made in their standard of 
living. As stated above, production team leaders continued doing farm work 
as part of their team. Most brigade leaders and those who carried out work in 
the communes were very conscientious about doing their best work. Every 
year when the harvest was complete, they faced criticism from their members 
and engaged in self-criticism. Great attention was paid to whether leaders 
took anything that belonged to the collectives for personal use. The leaders 
shouldered huge responsibilities with very little material reward. They did 
not exploit their members. 

Perhaps even more important, during China’s socialist develop- 
ment there was no external exploitation, which meant that no surplus was 
siphoned out of the country. In most colonial and semi-colonial countries— 
in addition to the exploitation of domestic landlords, capitalists, money- 
lenders, and bureaucrats—surplus is taken out of the country in profits for 
foreign monopoly capital and/or interest to foreign banks and international 


® See William Hinton, Shenfan, The Continuing Revolution in a Chinese Village, Ran- 
dom House, 1983. Hinton described the struggles in Long Bow Village in different 
parts of his book including how cadres were criticized by the peasants. 


60 


Question V. 


financial institutions such as the International Monetary Fund. Under the 
worker-peasant alliance, China’s socialist development adopted a self-reliant 
development strategy so that surplus created by the Chinese laboring class 
stayed in China to develop its industries and agriculture. 

What were the main factors in China’s self-reliant economic develop- 
ment? Why is self-reliant development only possible under socialism? 


The Two Major Dimensions of Self-reliant Development Strategy 


‘The first dimension of self-reliance is an economic development that 
relies on internal financing. In this world dominated by imperialism, less 
developed countries must mobilize their own resources for development. 
“Experts” in developmental economics created the myth that a poor country 
has to rely on external finance to develop. However, this myth has been shat- 
tered by what we have experienced in the past several decades. ‘The reality is 
that by relying on foreign investment and/or foreign loans, less developed 
countries lost many more resources than the very little they gained. They 
are much worse off after several decades of “development.” By relying on 
external finance, colonial and semi-colonial countries ended up owing huge 
debts to international monopoly capital and international financial institu- 
tions. International financial institutions dominated by monopoly capital 
and imperialist nations have used debt as an instrument to force Structural 
Adjustment Programs (SAP) onto debtors. 

Through SAPs these powerful outside forces have been able to dictate 
their internal economic and political affairs. Countries that have been placed 
under SAPs lose their autonomy to decide how to use their own resources 
to produce food and other necessities for their own people. Under SAPs 
productive resources shift from domestic consumption to produce export 
commodities in order to earn foreign exchange to pay interest on debt they 
owe. Meeting the interest payment for their ever-growing debt becomes the 
only objective for “development”; people’s basic needs are completely absent 
from any “development” program. Moreover, with the help of international 
trade and financial institutions, imperialist countries used this debt trap as a 
vehicle to shift the burden of economic crises to debtor countries. The result 
has been that large foreign multinationals have taken over many sectors of 
their economies including manufacturing, communication, and transporta- 
tion, as well as finance and banking. 


61 


From Victory to Defeat 


‘The second dimension of self-reliance in China’s socialist development 
is reliance on its own technology. Mao saw the importance of technology in 
economic development, but he often explained in his talks and writings that 
in order for a poor country like China to catch up with the West, China had 
to rely on its own technological development. He used an easily understood 
analogy to describe China’s technological needs: it must “walk on two legs.” 
One leg was adopting advanced up-to-date technology from the West when 
it was appropriate, by critically evaluating how such technology would fit 
its own development needs. However, a country like China could not just 
walk on this one leg. The other leg was the utilization of all different lev- 
els of technology, traditional and indigenous, as well as developing its own 
modern technology. The ability to utilize different levels of technology (the 
more advanced new technology and the dated old technology) for devel- 
opment in order to make use of all available (and scarce) machinery and 
equipment is only possible under socialism. As explained in Question IV 
the small-scale rural industries often did not use the most advanced. tech- 
nology, but they were able to serve the increasingly modernized agricultural 
sector by using the level of technology available to them—often machinery 
and equipment phased out by industries in the state sector. This is a good 
example of the “Walking on Two Legs” development strategy. In capitalist 
development older and less “efficient” technology is driven out of the market 
(and scrapped) by the newer and more “efficient” ones, essential to “planned 
obsolescence” or “creative destruction.” 

It is worthwhile to have a short discussion here on countries develop- 
ing their own technology. For a semi-colonial country developing its own 
technology is not simply a technical question. It involves a significant shift 
in ideology. At the time of Liberation China had been under foreign domi- 
nance for more than one hundred years. Foreign countries (from the West) 
repeatedly defeated China by using their superior weaponry and sophisti- 
cated technology. It was no wonder that Chinese people in general and Chi- 
nese intellectuals in particular regarded the superiority of foreign technology 
as absolute and believed that China could never catch up. This defeatist 
attitude had to be overcome. China was able to develop its own science and 
technology by painstakingly building a solid foundation from the basics, 
including writing its own basic textbooks on science and technology, instead 
of directly translating foreign copies. Making advancements in their own 
technology was proven possible during the socialist transition because the 


62 


Question V. 


ideology changed, leading people to believe that they had the ability. 

Also, unlike other developing countries, there was no brain drain from 
China during the socialist years. For many decades, year after year of unre- 
mitting brain drain from developing countries (including China once social- 
ism ended) to the Western countries has occurred with university educated 
young people as well as well-known scientists leaving their own countries to 
work in Western academies and high-tech industries. In fact, the brain drain 
has been much more serious than what is seen by the steady emigration of 
intellectuals because scientists in semi-colonial countries are incentivized to 
pursue research subjects, not according to the development needs of their 
own countries but according to whether their results are publishable in inter- 
national academic journals. The loss of resources from brain drain is as seri- 
ous as the draining of natural and financial resources from these countries. 

An economic model based on self-reliance made it possible for China 
to develop its economy during the socialist transition, to better the lives of its 
people and to consolidate the alliance between workers and peasants. China 
did receive financial and technological aid from the former Soviet Union in 
the 1950s. Soviet aid, given in the spirit of helping another socialist state, 
had a very positive impact on China’s heavy industry development. How- 
ever, the Soviet Union withdrew all of its technical personnel and left many 
projects unfinished in 1960 after the Chinese Communist Party criticized 
the Communist Party of the Soviet Union for its revisionist path after its 20" 
Congress in 1956. The Soviet Union also demanded immediate repayment 
of all China’s debt.“° China learned the importance of self-reliance from this 
experience. 

It is also necessary to point out that self-reliant development does not 
mean that a country has to totally rely on itself without trade with other 
nations. China always maintained that it welcomed foreign trade, as long 
as it benefited both trading partners and was carried out on a basis of equal 
treatment. For many years, however, China was not able to trade with many 
countries because of a United States imposed trade embargo. 

Under the self-reliance model, China did import technology from 
advanced capitalist countries. Alexander Eckstein wrote: “Complete-plant 
imports from Japan, Western Europe, and to some extent the United States 
are making a major contribution to the expansion of production capacity 


“6 Including the debt China owed to finance the Korean War. 


63 


From Victory to Defeat 


in the chemical fertilizer, petrochemical, and iron and steel industries, as 
well as in power generation and commercial aviation, in the 1970s.”“” China 
benefited from select technology imports because it was able to use them 
not to substitute for its own technology but to replicate them. After a for- 
eign-designed complete plant was imported and built, China was able to 
build a copy in a fairly short time. John G. Gurley, another expert on Chi- 
nese economy, said, “In the 1960s, China purchased four complete nitrog- 
enous-fertilizer plants from the Netherlands, Britain, and Italy, which were 
installed in 1966. It began building its own fertilizer plants in 1964, and 
around this time set a goal of one large-scale plant for each of the country’s 
180-190 districts and one smaller plant for each of the more than two thou- 
sand counties. In fact, much of the increased production of chemical fertil- 
izers in the 1960s came from the medium and small-scale plants that were 
constructed throughout the countryside during the decade.” Gurley added 
that China continued to import fertilizer from abroad as well. (Gurley, 249) 
The small-scale plants he was referring to were those owned and operated by 
communes and production brigades. 

Developing socialism in a country such as China, where the produc- 
tive forces were low, had some difficulties and challenges. (This will be fur- 
ther explored in Question VI.) Yet, despite these difficulties and challenges 
China succeeded. 

The overwhelming majority of less developed countries bought into 
the lie that they must rely on technology imported from advanced capitalist 
countries. However, once a country becomes dependent on imported tech- 
nology it must then adopt and accept the logic of capital and the way cap- 
ital defines efficiency. If we follow the logic of capital, efficiency is achieved 
when half of the workers are laid off and the remaining half work eighty 
hours a week. Self-reliance in technology is critically important and closely 
related to self-reliance in internal finance. When we contrast the self-reliant 
development strategy with the one relying on external finance and imported 
technology, the difference is clear. When a country becomes heavily indebted 
to international monopoly capital and international financial institutions, 
it has to forgo all other development objectives and use whatever means 
necessary to increase its exports to pay interest on its debt. However, when 
a country’s production is concentrating on exporting either agricultural 


“7 Eckstein, 1978, 107. 


64 


Question V. 


products or industrial products, it must also use advanced technology that 
is controlled by monopoly capital. Since China adopted capitalist develop- 
ment it has phased out almost all of the older capital equipment in its entire 
textile industry. It had to import the newest technology in textiles in order 
to make products that could compete with Taiwan, South Korea, and many 
other countries in the international textile and clothing market. As many 
textile factories closed down and tens of thousands of workers lost their jobs, 
China’s textile industry became dependent on export markets and imported 
technology, all of which are tightly controlled by international monopoly 
capital. 

China’ self-reliant strategy of development has proven that when a 
country is free of foreign and domestic exploitation, hardworking people can 
use the surplus they generate and the resources of its own country to develop 
the economy for the satisfaction of the current and future needs of its peo- 
ple and country. Imperialist propaganda wants us to believe that backward 
countries need financial resources and technology from advanced countries 
in order to develop. The success of China’s self-reliant development proved 
that this propaganda was a myth created by the imperialist countries, so that 
they could latch onto less developed but resource-rich countries and extract 
every bit of surplus from them. In this era of imperialism, imperialist coun- 
tries depend on colonial and semi-colonial countries to expand their capital 
accumulation, so they turn the truth upside down to create that myth. 


The Class Basis of China’s Self-Reliant Development 


‘The class basis of China’s self-reliant development strategy was the 
worker-peasant alliance. Under the worker-peasant alliance the State sup- 
ported the agricultural sector’s development. In the beginning stage of eco- 
nomic development in any society where there is little or no industry, surplus 
for development can only come from the agricultural sector. This means that 
the surplus needed to build industries has to be transferred from the agricul- 
tural sector to the industrial sector. China under socialism was no exception. 
‘The difference, however, is that in most colonial and semi-colonial coun- 
tries the agricultural sector does not get replenished after industry begins 
to develop. By pursuing the worker-peasant alliance, the socialist state in 
China continuously replenished the agricultural sector with industrial prod- 
ucts such as chemical fertilizer and pesticides, and agricultural machinery, 


65 


From Victory to Defeat 


such as tractors, threshers, harvesters, and equipment for power stations and 
irrigation systems. This was accomplished by State investment in agricultural 
input industries and by pricing their products low enough so that the com- 
munes could afford to buy them. The State also invested in infrastructure 
like large irrigation projects, such the famous Red Canal, which spanned 
several provinces. 

The workers’ state in China consciously and deliberately aimed to 
balance development between industry and agriculture, thus narrowing the 
standard of living gap between people in cities and the countryside. This was 
done by adjusting the price ratio between agricultural and industrial prod- 
ucts in favor of the agricultural sector, by lowering the relative share of taxes 
paid by the agricultural sector, by increased state investment in large agricul- 
tural infrastructure and agricultural machine/equipment industries, and by 
direct state grants to the collective sector. One example of a direct state grant 
was for education. The communes used state funds to build schools and pay 
teachers’ wages. The State also mobilized intellectuals in cities such as educa- 
tors, agricultural experts, and medical personnel to work in the countryside 
to raise the medical, educational, and cultural level for people living in rural 
areas. 

As stated earlier, China went through a socialist revolution while other 
colonial and semi-colonial countries did not. China’s socialist revolution led 
by the Chinese Communist Party was based on a very close alliance between 
workers and peasants. During the revolution the CCP formed a broad 
coalition with the national bourgeoisie on the basis of the worker-peasant 
alliance. Even before the final victory of the liberation war in 1949, Land 
Reform had already begun in the Liberated Areas and continued all over the 
countryside after Liberation. To this day many colonial and semi-colonial 
countries have not yet gone through genuine land reform. As explained in 
Question I, the national bourgeoisie in many colonial and semi-colonial 
countries is too weak to carry out land reform against the land-owning class. 
In the world of imperialism only the working class in these countries is able 
to lead a new democratic revolution to complete land reform and bring feu- 
dalism to an end. ‘The socialist revolution based on the worker-peasant alli- 
ance is the only way to end feudalism in the world of imperialism. However, 
in China, carrying out genuine land reform and ending feudalism would not 
have accomplished much unless the worker-peasant alliance continued to be 
at the foundation of charting the path for future development. 


66 


Question V. 


Land Reform alone could not have resolved the problems of back- 
wardness and poverty in China’s countryside. As noted earlier, polarization 
in China’s countryside became significant not long after Land Reform. With- 
out the collectivization of agriculture, polarization would have developed 
further and it would not have taken long for the land to be concentrated in 
the hands of new rich peasants. Rich peasants with enough land and farm 
tools could have hired laborers to work for them and then produced and 
sold their surplus grain using the proceeds to buy more land. A polarized 
countryside would have weakened or even destroyed the worker-peasant 
alliance, because workers would have been faced with a divided peasantry, 
and a polarized countryside would have promoted the class alliance between 
the rich peasants and grain merchants in cities. After the revolution, the 
proletariat, represented by the Chinese Communist Party, led socialist devel- 
opment by pursuing the close worker-peasant class alliance strategy, which 
made it possible to defend the class interests of the working people against 
potential domestic and foreign exploitation. This class alliance made it pos- 
sible for China to succeed in the socialist self-reliant development strategy. 

Only after the collectivization of agriculture was it possible to build 
an economic relationship between the (state-owned) industrial sector and 
the (collective-owned) agricultural sector. The exchange between the com- 
munes and the State was the material basis for the worker-peasant alliance. 
The worker-peasant alliance class strategy was the basis for the success of its 
socialist development. Imperialist countries deliberately prevent colonial and 
semi-colonial countries from developing their economies independently in 
order to achieve self-sufficiency in food and other basic necessities. Examin- 
ing post World War II history we find that the bourgeoisie in many colonial 
and semi-colonial countries had hoped to develop capitalism independently 
from the imperialist countries. However, sooner or later the bourgeoisie 
invariably found cooperation with foreign capital too attractive to their own 
class interest to refuse such an opportunity. This has become increasingly the 
case in the era of neoliberalism. Since the end of 1970s neoliberal strategy 
has further broken down the barriers for capital to expand across national 
borders. 

‘The result is that the production of all countries is more closely con- 
nected with the global market where the law of value has become applicable 
across national borders. Many colonial and semi-colonial countries, which 
had long concentrated on agricultural exports, now use more of their natu- 


67 


From Victory to Defeat 


ral resources to meet export demands. Mexican farmers produce fruits and 
vegetables to export to the United States, Chilean fishermen catch fish for 
Purina to make cat food for imperialist countries, Columbian farmers con- 
centrate on exporting flowers to beautify homes of petit bourgeois families 
in Europe and North America, Brazilian ranchers clear the natural forest to 
raise cattle to feed the hamburger industry in rich countries, and the list go 
on and on. The other side of the story is that people in these countries have 
become dependent on imports for their basic needs. Under NAFTA (North 
American Free Trade Agreement) large-scale US government subsidized corn 
flooded Mexico and wiped out Mexican corn producers and the indigenous 
seeds used for cultivation by many generations of peasants. 

During China’s war of liberation Mao saw that the interests of the 
national bourgeoisie were squeezed by foreign capital and that they did not 
have a future in a China taken over by imperialists; thus it was possible 
for them to play a positive role in the revolution. The national bourgeoisie 
agreed to be part of this broad coalition even though they understood the 
goal of the revolution was socialism, which meant that eventually their class 
would be eliminated. 

The national bourgeoisie in colonial and semi-colonial countries 
wanted to develop capitalism independent of imperialist powers—there- 
fore they were a positive force in anti-imperialist struggles. They were 
called “national bourgeoisie” to distinguish them from the bourgeoisie that 
were closely connected with the foreign capital, also called “compradors.” 
“National” meant that they could play a positive role in the national lib- 
eration movement and had a progressive meaning. In the early part of the 
post-WWII era the national bourgeoisie led and joined national liberation 
movements in many parts of the world. 

As described earlier, independent capitalist development pursued by 
the national bourgeoisie failed completely in the 1980s. In the neoliberal 
era the bourgeoisie in colonial and semi-colonial countries today play a 
rather different role when compared with the past. When production and 
exchange in these countries became so closely connected to the monopoly 
capital in imperialist countries it created the opportunity for the bourgeoisie 
to work closely with the global monopoly capital of the imperialist coun- 
tries. The bourgeoisie that work closely with foreign monopoly capital has 
been rewarded handsomely. For this reason I am not so sure they should 
still be called “national bourgeoisie.” With fewer and fewer exceptions the 


68 


Question V. 


bourgeoisie class in semi-colonial countries today sells the interests of their 
own country to monopoly capital to enrich themselves. They do not do 
anything that promotes the interests of their own country. Therefore, in the 
anti-imperialist movement should the workers and peasants who lead the 
struggle continue to form a coalition with the bourgeoisie? Or should the 
bourgeoisie be a target in the fight against imperialism? Mao's worker-peas- 
ant alliance strategy for liberation has stood the test of time; it is still the only 
class strategy in the colonial and semi-colonial world where the majority of 
the working people are peasants. However, should Mao’s strategy of form- 
ing coalitions with the bourgeoisie be modified in the neoliberal phase of 
imperialism? The nature of bourgeoisie in today’s colonial and semi-colonial 
countries is a question today’s revolutionaries need to consider carefully. 


69 


From Victory to Defeat 


Question VI. 


What Challenges and Difficulties did China Face During Socialist 
Construction? 


In the Chinese Revolution and the Chinese Communist Party, Mao ana- 
lyzed China’s society as semi-colonial and semi-feudal. Mao led China to win 
the socialist revolution and to develop socialism, despite the fact that China’s 
capitalist development was still in its very early stage. Developing socialism 
in a country where its productive forces were minimally developed presented 
some serious challenges and difficulties. Even with these serious challenges, 
China made spectacular achievements during the socialist construction. In 
hindsight we have a better understanding of the challenges China faced and 
the kinds of problems they created during socialist development. 

An analysis of these challenges can not only help other semi-colonial 
and semi-feudal countries in their pursuit of socialist development, it can 
also help explain at least partially why, after a few short decades, China’s suc- 
cessful socialist development that benefited hundreds of millions of people 
was aborted in 1978. Of course, there were those who betrayed the socialist 
cause and in China those traitors have since been clearly identified. But sim- 
ply calling them traitors does not help us understand the underlying causes 
for their betrayal. Unlike religion, socialism does not depend on faith or 
saintly behavior. Marxists must investigate the concrete situation and come 
up with an analysis based on the objective and subjective factors in China 
at that time. 

As noted earlier, Karl Marx believed that the proletariat in advanced 
capitalist countries were likely the first ones to make socialist revolution and 
develop socialism. His reasoning was that when capitalism reaches its mature 
stage, the contradictions between the private ownership of means of produc- 
tion and social production deepens. This contradiction prevents productive 
forces from further development unless there is a change in the relations 
of production—a revolution that appropriates the private ownership of the 
means of production. 

In the mature stage capitalism, where production is already oper- 
ating at a very large scale, the transfer of ownership from private to pub- 
lic—although it would require tremendous political, economic, and social 
struggles—could proceed without too many complications, because both 


70 


Question VI. 


industrial and agricultural production would already be operating at the 
same scale. After the revolution the ownership of large industrial complexes 
and large-scale farms could be transferred to the State, changing private 
ownership to public. However, in a country like China (in 1949) and in 
other semi-colonial and semi-feudal countries, there were only some small- 
scale industrial enterprises in cities and small-scale peasant family farming 
in the countryside. Therefore, it wasn’t possible to transfer the means of 
production from private ownership to one single public ownership. Instead, 
the State took over the means of production of industrial enterprises and in 
agriculture the three-tier communes collectively owned the means of pro- 
duction in agriculture. During the entire period of socialist development in 
China, state ownership and collective ownership co-existed. Mao foresaw 
the potential problems created from the two types of ownership and often 
expressed concern. 

After the transfer of ownership of means of production to one single 
public ownership in countries where capitalism has reached the advanced 
stage of development, there would be continued struggle to make the 
socialist economy run smoothly in the economic base. Also, probably more 
importantly, there would be ongoing struggle to continuously meet chal- 
lenges in the superstructure—political, ideological, and cultural—with the 
goal to eventually bring commodity production to an end. During this time 
of transition, the volume and the scope of commodity production would 
be gradually reduced to an insignificant level and eventually fade away. As 
commodity production fades away, the law of value (equal value exchange) 
would cease to dominate people’s consciousness. Then we will have reached 
socialism—the early stage of communism. 

However, in socialist China, when the two types of ownership coex- 
isted, the exchange between the state sector and the collective sector and 
within the collective sector increased. Most of these exchanges were com- 
modity exchanges, although they were strictly regulated. Therefore, when 
productive forces developed under the two types of ownership, commodity 
production, instead of decreasing in volume and scope, increased in both. It 
is reasonable to assume that when commodity production increased in both 
volume and scope the law of value continued to play a role and was likely to 
play an increasingly important role. In China’s case, even though regulation 
helped prevent the law of value from expanding without bounds, neither 
commodity production nor the law of value could be regulated out of exis- 


71 


From Victory to Defeat 


tence. These were the capitalist elements at work in China’s growing socialist 
economy. Not only must we recognize them, but we must also thoroughly 
reckon with them in order to understand the challenges they posed to Chi- 
na’s socialist development. 

Below is an attempt to analyze the challenges posed by the low-level of 
development of productive forces during socialist construction. 


The Coexistence of Two Types of Ownership of the Means of Produc- 
tion 


As described earlier, under collective ownership China’s agriculture 
made tremendous progress in building agricultural infrastructure, modern- 
izing and increasing production, and brought tremendous improvements 
to people’s lives. These achievements were made possible by the hard work 
of the peasants and the economic relationship that the collective sector had 
with the state sector. As explained above, the means of production in agri- 
culture were collectively owned by the communes, which had three tiers of 
ownership: the commune, the brigade, and the team. The team was the basic 
accounting unit. At this basic accounting level peasant households put their 
resources—land, farm tools, and labor—together and distributed the team’s 
output according to the labor contributed by team members. The produc- 
tion team was in fact a rather small unit of around 20 peasant households, 
but it was difficult to enlarge the basic accounting unit to the brigade level, 
which would expand the number of households to several times of the size 
of the team. The reason for the difficulty was that enlarging the size of the 
basic accounting unit to the brigade level by combining resources of several 
teams would even out the income of all the teams. Such consolidation would 
have disadvantaged the higher income teams by pulling their income down 
to the average. 

This does not mean it would be impossible to enlarge the basic 
accounting unit—only that it would require time. When the brigade owned 
more and more large agricultural machinery and equipment (such as trac- 
tors, combines, threshers, and planters) and made them available for all 
teams to use, then the differences among the teams became relatively small, 
and every team benefitted although maybe not equally. The same is true for 
consolidating several brigades into a commune as the basic accounting unit. 
During socialism, many communes, especially the rich ones, were able to use 


72 


Question VI. 


their accumulation funds to build large-scale irrigation projects including 
electric pumping stations, to purchase large agricultural instruments and to 
build factories. These kinds of development paved the way to enlarge the 
basic accounting unit to the commune level. By 1978, however, when Deng 
carried out the capitalist reform, very few communes had been able to grow 
the basic accounting unit to the brigade level. 

We know how capitalism polarizes society, while socialism does the 
opposite. However, in the concrete case of China when there were two types 
of ownership, the equalizing impact was limited. The reason is that while 
state ownership enabled different parts of China to develop more evenly, col- 
lective ownership was able to equalize development within units, such as the 
teams, but it could not help equalize income among collectives (brigades and 
communes). It was even less possible across different regions. As explained 
earlier, under state ownership more advanced industrial enterprises helped 
set up and develop other new industrial enterprises by aiding them with 
machinery and equipment, as well as technical personnel, without mone- 
tary or any other compensation. This was because all industrial enterprises 
were under the same unified accounting unit. Thus, the exchanges between 
or among different enterprises were not commodity transactions. The State 
could deliberately even out the industrial development in different parts of 
the country by allocating more resources to the less industrialized areas. That 
was how industrialization expanded from China’s East and Northeast, where 
industries were more developed to the West and Northwest where barely 
any industries had existed. Moreover, all workers of state-owned enterprises 
were paid according to the same wage scale with small adjustments made 
accounting for the regional differences in the cost of living. This also had 
an equalizing effect on workers’ standard of living across the whole country. 

Under collective ownership equalization did take place within a col- 
lective unit, especially within the basic account unit: the productive team. 
Within the productive team the worth of each work point was the same, but 
the number of work points earned from a day of labor by its members still 
ranged between four to ten depending on the physical strength and techni- 
cal skills required. Within a productive brigade, the levels of income among 
the teams were only somewhat equalized, because team members shared 
what the brigade and the commune was able to provide. On a much wider 
scale, equalization did not take place across different communes in differ- 
ent regions. Instead, collective ownership resulted in polarization; the rich 


73 


From Victory to Defeat 


communes in rich regions became relatively richer and the poor communes 
in more backward regions became relatively poorer. During the early 1970s 
when rural industrialization began, the income gaps between the richer 
and the poorer communes, as well as the gap in the rates of development, 
increased. In developing socialism in countries where productive forces are 
at a low level of development, it is necessary to maintain the two-type own- 
ership—but for how long? 

In Mao’s A Critique of Soviet Economics he posed the question in point 
19: “Is Long-Term Coexistence Between Two Types of Socialist Ownership 
Possible?” He agreed with the Soviet textbook that a socialist state and social- 
ist construction couldn't be established on two different economic bases for 
any length of time. He said, “We therefore extend the logic to reach the 
following conclusion: the socialist state and socialist construction cannot 
be established for any great length of time on the basis of ownership by the 
whole people and the ownership by the collective as two different bases of 
ownership.”“* He continued to say that in the Soviet Union the period of 
coexistence had lasted too long and that “the contradictions between the 
two types of ownership are in reality contradictions between workers and 
peasants.” The contradictions between workers and peasants were contra- 
dictions among the people that resulted from the coexistence of two types of 
ownership necessary due to the low level of development. 

During the socialist transition in advanced capitalist countries, how- 
ever, there would not be a need for the coexistence of two types of owner- 
ship. Advanced capitalist countries would face challenges that are different 
from that of China and other less developed countries. 

China was and still is a very large and very diverse country. Before 
Liberation there had been very little industrial development, and the dif- 
ferences in the level of agricultural development in different parts of the 
country were mostly due to their natural endowments—the richness of the 
soil, the availability of water, and the climate. Trading centers that had land 
and water transportation became very prosperous. For example, the Yangtze 
River Delta was traditionally rich in agricultural production due to its mod- 
erate weather, rich soil, and plentiful water resources. Before Liberation, this 
area also led the nation in industrial production in cities such as Shanghai. 


48 Mao Zedong, A Critique of Soviet Economics, translated by Moss Roberts, Monthly 
Reviews Press, 1977, 53. 


® Thid., 53-54. 
74 


Question VI. 


A city like Shanghai had the advantage of being a seaport where most trade 
with the outside took place, and it was also connected to China’s vast interior 
by land and water transportation. 

During socialist development, the unified state ownership of indus- 
trial enterprises in different geographic areas with differences in productive 
facilities and technological sophistication were evened out (equalized), with 
more advanced enterprises helping less advanced enterprises. Since these 
enterprises belonged to a single owner, resources could be moved around 
according to an economic plan, and there was no need to compensate the 
more advanced enterprises for helping less advanced enterprises. On the 
other hand, the collective ownership (though better than private ownership) 
in the countryside created not only polarization among communes and 
regions but also contradictions between the state sector and the collective 
sector. These contradictions could not be easily resolved when the two types 
of ownership existed side-by-side. This posed an important challenge for 
development. 

It is easier to understand the complexities of the situation by examin- 
ing some concrete issues. One major issue was how to produce enough food 
for the Chinese people. There was a large gap in grain production between 
different regions. Grain production was high in the Yangtze River Delta area 
and in China’s southern provinces, while in other areas grain production 
was much lower due to the poor quality of land and scarce water resources. 
‘These areas did not produce enough grain to feed the people. Therefore, 
grain had to be shipped from the areas where there were surpluses to areas 
where grain supplies were insufficient. During socialist development, great 
emphasis was placed on self-reliance both on the national and on regional 
levels. Peasants in poor areas worked extremely hard to be self-sufficient in 
food. However, the country as a whole still had to depend on grain and other 
agricultural output from rich agricultural areas. Therefore, the State, looking 
after the interests of the whole nation, had to persuade the communes in the 
rich agricultural areas to continue putting more resources into agriculture in 
order to ship food to poorer agricultural areas. As stated earlier, areas rich in 
agriculture were also more developed in industry. Agricultural production 
has lower rates of return compared to industrial development. The interest 
of the collectives in the rich areas was to invest more in industries for faster 
and higher returns. However, the State regulated that they had to retain 40% 
of their earnings to be invested in agriculture and in their welfare fund. The 


75 


From Victory to Defeat 


production brigade and communes that owned the industrial enterprises 
followed the regulations, but not without resentment. 

During my trip to China in 1979 when the capitalist reform had just 
begun, I visited a production brigade of a rich commune in a rich county. 
This brigade owned a light bulb factory, which was established in the mid- 
1960s, when China's agriculture stabilized after the three difficult years 
(1950-61). During the early years, the factory only had enough money to 
rent three rooms to produce simple light bulbs. By 1979 it was producing a 
large variety of light bulbs including light bulbs for automobiles, florescent 
lights, and many others. The factory under collective ownership had the 
characteristics of a capitalist enterprise. It was eager to expand its market 
so it could increase its sales and enlarge its revenue. This collectively owned 
industry and others like it found their relationship with the State restrictive. 

Beginning in the mid-1960s many of these collectively owned indus- 
trial enterprises sprouted up in rich communes and there was not enough 
time to incorporate them into the national economic plan as quickly as they 
developed. I do not have enough information to conclusively prove this was 
the fact, but the criticisms launched against these enterprises lend my assess- 
ment validity. The criticism of these brigade/commune-owned industrial 
enterprises charged that in order to acquire raw materials, they went through 
private connections to get what they needed from the state enterprises. This 
kind of criticism usually came from the Left, which disliked what was going 
on but did not know how to resolve the contradiction. They often used 
the wrong tactics by blocking these kinds of dealings through criticism and 
enforcing new rules. The actions of the Left (some might call them “ultra- 
Left”) further alienated these enterprises. The light bulb factory was likely to 
be a strong supporter of Deng’s capitalist reform. The manager of the light 
bulb factory told me that after the capitalist reform began, they were very 
happy that a business in Hong Kong came to order Christmas lights from 
them. A collectively owned small factory found the opportunity to expand 
its production through new policies under Deng’s reform. There are many 
more examples like this light bulb factory. It is important for us to identify 
the forces in China that supported Deng’s capitalist reform; it is a mistake 
to think Deng did it single handedly as if he possessed some magic power. 

Chinas success in making revolution and developing socialism 
depended on the strong alliance between the workers and peasants. During 
socialist construction the CCP was able to use state policies to strengthen 


76 


Question VI. 


their alliance when the economic base was under the coexistence of state 
ownership and collective ownership. These policies resolved the contradic- 
tions between the agricultural and industrial sectors, which in reality were 
contradictions between workers and peasants. Resolving contradictions 
between workers and peasants was easier when the economy was just begin- 
ning to develop. However, as the economy developed further in the 1970s, 
the contradictions became more numerous and complex. (See below.) In 
the meantime, those who opposed socialism manipulated the contradictions 
and opportunistically turned them into contradictions between the people 
and the enemy. 


Low Level of Development and Other Contradictions Among the Peo- 
ple 


‘The low level of productive forces posed challenges resulting in con- 
tradictions among the people. These kinds of contradictions can be resolved 
by putting appropriate and timely policies in place. 

Concretely, in China, when the output level was very low, one chal- 
lenge was finding the right relationship between accumulation and con- 
sumption. For example, in order to speed up development in agriculture, 
enough resources had to be accumulated into agricultural machinery and 
equipment, building infrastructure and land improvement. On the other 
hand, as a poor country there was an urgent need to provide adequate food 
and other necessities of life for the people. In 1959 right after the com- 
munes were established, Mao saw the contradiction between accumulation 
and consumption as a serious issue and quickly applied the appropriate pol- 
icy to resolve it. 

In 1958 there were good harvests. The production of grain and other 
agricultural products went up yet the State had problems fulfilling its pur- 
chasing quotas in grain and other products. Mao went to Zhengzhou, Henan 
to investigate the problem in 1959 and gave three talks during the Zheng- 
zhou (Agricultural) Conference in February and March 1959." In these talks 
he reported what he found and suggested solutions. Mao explained that the 
reason behind the difficulty in fulfilling the government’s purchasing quotas 
was that peasants reported lower production figures than the actual amounts 


°° Mao Zedong’s Talks during the Zhengzhou Conference February and March, 
1959 in Long Live Mao Zedong Thought, 1967, 8-53. 


77 


From Victory to Defeat 


they had harvested. He found that peasants under-reported to avoid paying 
more taxes and/or other levies imposed on them from higher yields. Accord- 
ing to Mao’s estimate, if peasants had reported their production honestly 
then after taxes and other levies the peasants would have only 30-35% of 
their production left for their own consumption. By not reporting the real 
production numbers the peasants were able to retain another 10-15% of 
what they had produced. 

Mao described the six layers of administration units above the pro- 
duction team: the central government (State), the provincial government, 
the regional government, the county government, the commune and the 
brigade. After deductions made by all the different levels of government, the 
peasants only retained 30% of their production. He said the level of taxes 
and other levies was too high; they amounted to taking away peasants’ pro- 
duction without compensation. Mao stood on the side of peasants, saying 
that the peasants had a right to guard what was theirs and supported their 
action to falsify their production numbers. His suggestions to resolve the 
contradiction was to first consider how much the peasants would need to 
live and then calculate the amount of taxes and levies. He believed that the 
peasants should be able to keep 50% of their production for their consump- 
tion, state taxes limited to 7-10%, and the commune accumulation fund 
limited to around 15-18%, with the remaining funds allocated for other 
administrative expenses. Mao advised the communes not to be too eager 
to invest in agricultural machinery and equipment and build large-scale 
infrastructure so the amount collected for the accumulation fund could be 
reduced. He also put forth that paid administrators at different levels of gov- 
ernments should be kept at an absolute minimum; he specifically mentioned 
that artists and cultural groups should continue their work in agricultural 
production; encouraged cadres to understand the lives of ordinary peasants 
by visiting and staying with them; and emphasized the importance of a close 
relationship between the cadres and peasants. 

‘There was also dissatisfaction in poorer communes. As explained ear- 
lier, the productive team first paid taxes to the State and then paid the com- 
mune to cover the accumulation and welfare funds. A portion of the rest was 
distributed to team members as quota grain. ‘The leftovers were used to pay 
team members according to the work points they earned during the year. 
The problem with the very poor commune/teams was that the total income 
of the team was so meager that often after all the deductions were made, 


78 


Question VI. 


there was little left for distribution according to work points earned. In those 
teams/communes people who worked hard all year would not receive much 
above the quota grain that everyone received. As a result they did not receive 
any compensation for their labor. This did not fulfill the distribution princi- 
ple of “to each according to his/her labor.” 

According to William Hinton’s assessment, by the time the communes 
were dissolved in 1985, one third of all communes had done exceedingly 
well, the third in the middle had done well, but the bottom third had done 
poorly. With the exception of the very poor teams, each member received 
an income according to work points accumulated from the labor he/she 
contributed. However, at the national level the worth of one day’s labor 
differed tremendously among rich and poor communes. The worth of one 
day’s labor in rich communes could be ten times as much as that of the 
poor communes. The collective ownership of means of production could 
only equalize the income within the team and somewhat within the brigade 
and the commune, but not among different communes or across different 
regions. In fact, during China’s socialist development, in the countryside the 
rich got richer and the poor got poorer. The rich communes and the poor 
communes faced very different sets of problems. Therefore, there could not 
be one single solution. The worker-peasant alliance policies during the land 
reform and during the collectivization of agriculture had been applied more 
or less uniformly in different parts of the countryside, but by the early 1970s 
there was no policy that could be applied with such uniformity to deal with 
all the new situations. Due to the diverse conditions in different parts of 
China’s countryside, an appropriate worker-peasant alliance policy for rich 
regions would have to be very different from that of poor regions. The more 
differentiated the levels of development in China’s countryside, the more 
complicated and individualized the policy needed to be. 

Another contradiction among the people related to the low level of 
development of productive forces was that some production team members 
sought opportunities to earn some money outside of their work points earned 
from tending the land, planting and harvesting. Since commodity exchanges 
still existed at different levels of the communes, there were opportunities to 
earn extra income from trading. Additionally, each farm household still had 
a private lot. Peasants used these private lots to grow some vegetables and to 
raise a couple of pigs and chickens to supplement their diet. The low level 
of productive forces meant that the worth of each work point remained low, 


79 


From Victory to Defeat 


so the opportunity to produce more in the private plots and sell the extra 
products in the free markets was very attractive. This provided the capitalist 
roaders the opportunity to propagate their policy of “san zi yi bao” (three 
self’s and one contract), which meant a policy: 1) to enlarge the private plots 
of land; 2) to expand the free markets; 3) for peasant households to sign con- 
tracts with the government, which would stipulate the prices and quantities 
of grain the peasant households were obligated to sell. The contract allowed 
peasants to keep whatever they made above the amounts stipulated in the 
contract as “profit” and suffered a “loss” when sales did not cover the costs. 
Advocates of this policy claimed that it would motivate peasants to work 
harder and produce more. 

Mao opposed this policy. It was obvious that if the private lots and free 
markets continued to expand, peasants would spend more and more time 
and labor on their private plots and eventually collective ownership would 
collapse. Peasant families would go back to farming their own small pieces of 
land, wiping out all the infrastructure built under the three-tiered commune 
ownership, and rendering the machinery and equipment bought from the 
accumulation fund useless, because it would have been impossible to divide 
and distribute them to individual households. (This happened as described 
after the Capitalist Reform. See Question VII.) Yet the private plots and the 
free markets were still needed for the time being. Only when the productive 
forces reached a higher level, when the work points earned from one day of 
work on the collectively owned land was worth more than a day of work 
on the family’s private lot, would peasants no longer focus their efforts on 
their private plots. Before reaching that level of development, private plots 
could not be forcibly taken away, nor the free markets closed. In the mean- 
time, as long as the private lots and free market existed, the opponents of 
socialism continued to try to tear collective ownership apart, as evidenced 
by Deng Xiaoping’s immediate de-collectivization of agriculture as soon as 
he and his supporters seized power. By 1985 the process of de-collectiviza- 
tion was complete and Chinese peasants went back to individual farming. 
Most of the infrastructure peasants had worked so hard to build fell into 
disrepair. Capitalist propagandists claim that the problem of socialist China 
was that political chaos made economic development impossible and the 
economic stagnation made Deng’s capitalist reform necessary. In fact, the 
exact opposite was true. The productive forces developed very rapidly and 
such development created new contradictions, which were not resolved in 


80 


Question VI. 


a timely fashion. These contradictions meant that workers and peasants no 
longer had a strong unified material basis on which to solidify their alliance. 
The CCP’s sound worker-peasant alliance policies gave the working people 
the solid foundation to win the revolutionary war and to build a socialist 
country. However, under collective ownership and how it was linked to state 
ownership, China’s countryside developed rapidly but unevenly. The uneven 
development of China’s countryside made it very difficult and complicated 
to advance the worker-peasant alliance. In less developed countries where 
peasants are the majority of the working population, the strength of work- 
ing people can only be as strong as the unity between workers and peas- 
ants. Those in the CCP who favored capitalist development for China took 
advantage of the weakening unity between workers and peasants and made 
their own alliances with those who saw their own potential for capitalist 
development. 

When building socialism with a low level of productive forces, capital- 
ist elements continue to be part of the development. When commodity pro- 
duction continues to exist and even expands in scope, the law of value plays 
a role. The law of value manifested in the contradictions among the people, 
which could then transform into contradictions between the people and the 
enemy, necessitating the two-line struggle. Of course, two-line struggle will 
also exist in socialist development in imperialist countries where the pro- 
ductive forces are already fully developed. However, that two-line struggle 
will be different. The two-line struggle in socialist development in countries 
with fully developed productive forces will probably be concentrated in the 
superstructure and not so much in the economic base. In countries where 
productive forces are still at a low level of development, the two-line struggle 
is more concentrated in the economic base where two types of ownership 
coexist and commodity production continues to expand. China faced this 
critical challenge during its socialist development. This is still a preliminary 
analysis and much more work and discussion are needed to understand the 
role of the law of value when commodity production continues to exist and 
expand. 


The Problem of Restricting the Power of Cadres in State-Owned Indus- 
trial Enterprises 


One of the biggest challenges faced by any country during the social- 


81 


From Victory to Defeat 


ist transition is how to restrict the power of cadres who are in charge of the 
state-owned enterprises. This challenge is not limited to the less developed 
countries like China; countries whose productive forces are fully developed 
would also face the same challenge. How cadres use power bestowed by the 
State is of critical importance. Whether they use their power to serve the 
socialist cause or to become the agents of capital determines the direction of 
the transition. 

In China concrete measures limited the power of the cadres in state 
enterprises. The most important measure was to raise the class-consciousness 
of workers. Especially after the Cultural Revolution, factories adhering to 
the principles of the Angang Constitution were able to revolutionize indus- 
trial organization. The Angang Constitution called for putting proletarian 
politics in command and articulated concrete methods to transform the 
relationship between ordinary workers and cadres in leadership. Instead of 
always following orders given by cadres, workers were given the opportu- 
nity to express their opinions and encouraged to take initiative in advanc- 
ing technological changes. And, of course, permanent employment status, 
as opposed to temporary employment under the contract labor system 
advocated by Liu Shaoqi, made the factory a permanent place for workers. 
During the socialist period, workers in industrial enterprises had a sense of 
ownership. When Deng carried out his capitalist reform and the machinery, 
equipment, and factory buildings were auctioned off, many workers strug- 
gled mightily to defend them. However, in the end they were not strong 
enough to resist the takeover. 

For the real changes in the relationship between the cadres and work- 
ers to take root, much more time and more fundamental change would 
be needed because the division in the responsibilities of the cadres and 
the workers remained largely unchanged. The cadres continued their core 
responsibility of disbursing funds appropriated by the State, including funds 
for current operations, investments, and wages. The disbursing of these dif- 
ferent kinds of funds represented real power. During the socialist period, 
the overwhelming majority of cadres did everything they could to “serve 
the people” and did not cross boundaries to abuse the power they possessed. 
Part of the reason was that they did not abandon their principles and contin- 
ued to put public interests above their own self-interest. Additionally, they 
understood that those who held higher positions in the government and 
devoted themselves to work for the benefit of the people would not tolerate 


82 


Question VI. 


graft and bribery. Moreover, due to repeated mass movements they were very 
aware that they were under the watchful eyes of the workers and the masses. 
However, this does not negate the reality of their power and the temptation 
to use it for self-interest. Many of these cadres supported Deng’s capitalist 
reform. Deng’s capitalist reform legitimized turning managers’ power into 
personal wealth. It opened the floodgates of tremendous amounts of wealth 
to be siphoned from state enterprises into the pockets of these former cadres. 
Further discussion will follow in Question VII. 

At the end of the liberation war, how to transfer power possessed by 
members of the Communist Party who held important positions in manag- 
ing the State to the vast number of masses was and continues to be one of 
the biggest challenges to all those who take up the task of building socialism. 
China’s experience has shown that class struggle continues after Liberation. 
The outcome of this struggle determines the direction of the transition: 
socialist or capitalist. In 1976 the strength of the bourgeoisie was stronger 
than that of the proletariat. Forces representing the proletariat were defeated. 
The direction of the transition was reversed from socialism to capitalism. As 
Mao once said, on the long road to final victory there will be many twists 
and turns but the future is always bright. The proletariat has to analyze and 
evaluate reasons for each defeat and be prepared for the continuation of the 
struggle. 

‘The brief analysis above on the challenges China faced during the 
socialist transition points out the only most obvious. It is far from com- 
plete; more research is needed. I believe that revolutionaries today whose 
goal is to build a brand new socialist society need to spend time and effort to 
thoroughly study China’s concrete experiences where workers and peasants 
successfully built a socialist society but were ultimately defeated. 


83 


From Victory to Defeat 


Question VII. 


What has happened to China and Chinese people after the count- 


er-revolutionaries seized power in 1976? 


Seizing Political Power and Implementing Capitalist Reform 


After Mao Zedong died in September 1976 a group of capitalists 
within the Chinese Communist Party staged a coup, arrested the “Gang of 
Four” (Jiang Qing, Yao Wenyuan, Zhang Chungiao, and Wang Hongwen), 
and seized political power. The new regime propagated their version of the 
historical development of the revolution and denounced the Cultural Rev- 
olution as a mistake Mao made in his old age. After a short period of tran- 
sition, the new regime officially began its Reform at the conclusion of the 
Third Plenary Session of the Eleventh Congress of the Chinese Communist 
Party in December 1978. The new regime, led by Deng Xiaoping, purported 
to not have a definite plan for its Reform and Opening Up program claim- 
ing it would “cross the river by touching the stones’—meaning the Reform 
would proceed one step at a time without following a grand plan. ‘The reason 
for this pretense was that Deng tried to avoid making public the concrete 
capitalist projects he planned to put in place. By examining the concrete pol- 
icies that Deng’s Reform enacted, however, one can see it was in fact a well 
thought out and well-integrated plan. The Reform put together all the cap- 
italist projects Liu and Deng had attempted to carry out during the 1950s 
and 1960s without success. Given that experience, Deng knew that when 
the Reform began, they had to disguise the capitalist nature of the projects, 
because people still remembered them. Therefore, they claimed, and have 
continued to claim, the Reform is “socialism with Chinese characters.” 

Deng’s Reform consisted of two interrelated components: capitalist 
reform in China and opening up China’s economy to link it with the inter- 
national capitalist system. Within a short amount of time, Deng and his 
followers began to dismantle the socialist economic and social system built 
during 19561976 by fundamentally changing the relations of production, as 
well as the superstructure, from socialist to capitalist. The Reformers under- 
stood that the principal opponents of their Reform would be the working 
people (workers and peasants) so their class strategy was to create disunity 
among the workers to weaken their power and to break up the close alliance 


84 


Question VII. 


between workers and peasants. During the socialist construction, the State 
and collective ownership of the means of production was fundamental to the 
socialist class strategy: the unity of workers and their close alliance with peas- 
ants. To be successful the capitalist Reformers had to attack this economic 
base. However, since the socialist superstructure supported the socialist eco- 
nomic base, the capitalist Reformers had also to fundamentally change the 
superstructure from socialist to capitalist. 


Fundamental Changes in the Relations of Production 


1) The Industrial Sector 


‘The goal of the capitalist reform was to change the former state-owned 
industrial enterprises, which had been in the process of phasing out com- 
modity production, into privately owned profit-making enterprises. In the 
process of transforming these industrial enterprises the Reform also changed 
labor power, which was in the process of being phased out as a commodity 
during the socialist transition, back into a commodity to be bought and 
sold—in order to reverse the process of socialist reform discussed in Ques- 
tion II. (A). 

During the socialist transition, Liu Shaogi and Deng Xiaoping made 
repeated attempts to replace the permanent workers in state-owned enter- 
prises with temporary contract workers—but before they seized political 
power their attempts were defeated. Liu and Deng saw that the abolishment 
of permanent employment status in state enterprises would enable peasants 
to compete with workers for jobs, thus putting downward pressure on wages 
and benefits of industrial workers. They saw competition among workers 
and between workers and peasants as key to capital accumulation, which 
they believed would speed up economic development. Mao, on the other 
hand, regarded permanent employment as a fundamental right of workers 
in state enterprises during the socialist era. He correctly saw that permanent 
employment strengthened the power of workers, because it was a prereq- 
uisite for workers in state ownership to assert their influence on managing 
factories in order to eventually lead the factories. If the working class was to 
become the masters of their socialist country they had to start by becoming 
masters of the factories in which they worked. 

‘The struggle for permanent employment status versus replacing per- 
manent workers with temporary workers was part of the overall two-line 


85 


From Victory to Defeat 


struggle between the socialist forces and the capitalist roaders. During and 
following the Cultural Revolution, the socialist forces had the upper hand, 
until the capitalists seized power in 1976. 

In the mid-1980s when the new regime embarked on its reform of 
state enterprises to eventually privatize them, new factory managers were 
given more and more autonomy to run the factories, including the right to 
hire and fire workers and replace permanent workers with temporary ones. 
Before the regime began its formal restructuring of state enterprises, man- 
agement applied all kinds of tactics to divide the workers, including re-in- 
troducing “material incentives” in wage payment, such as paying bonuses 
and piece-wage rates. However, most workers recognized that “material 
incentives,” which had been criticized during the Cultural Revolution, was 
a tactic to divide workers and they refused to go along. Workers resisted the 
Reformers’ attempt to use material incentives as a tactic to entice them to 
work faster and compete with one another. During the early 1980s the rate 
of inflation went up so in many factories workers simply divided up the 
total amount of bonuses and distributed them equally as a way to soften the 
impact of the rising cost of living. 

Question II. (A) explained how phasing out commodity production 
was basic to transforming the relations of production in state enterprises. 
The process of phasing out commodity production in state enterprises meant 
that production in state enterprises no longer followed the law of value to 
maximize profits, but rather to produce useful products according to an eco- 
nomic plan. During socialist construction, all state enterprises were under 
one unified accounting system and each enterprise no longer calculated their 
own “revenue” and “cost” to arrive at its own “profit” or “loss.” The State 
bought all their products and supplied all materials needed for their produc- 
tion. The State also transferred a “wage fund” to pay the workers’ wages and 
benefits. The goal of capitalist reform was exactly the opposite. It aimed to 
transform each state enterprise from producing useful products according to 
an economic plan into a separate unit, each seeking to maximize its profits 
and competing against one another for survival. 

Following the passage of the Economic Structure Reform (of indus- 
tries) in 1985, the State began to contract out state enterprises to individuals 
or teams of managers. Who had the opportunity to contract these enter- 
prises? Only those who were in positions of power or those who had close 
connections with those in power. The new managers of these enterprises 


86 


Question VII. 


were given the authority to separate parts of the enterprise that were not 
profitable by selling or leasing them and to keep the parts that were prof- 
itable for themselves. These new profit-making enterprises were allowed to 
keep portions of the profits and handed the rest to the State. Later, manag- 
ers of these new enterprises were allowed to keep all the profits they made, 
extracted from the workers’ surplus labor, and only paid taxes on their earn- 
ings to the State—just like private corporations in other capitalist countries. 
Today, there are only a few key industries—mostly in national defense (or 
defense related), public utilities, and transportation—that remain under 
state ownership. Even these enterprises operate like capitalist corporations; 
the only difference is that they are required to fulfill their obligations to the 
State. A number of Chinese state and private enterprises had their Initial 
Public Offering (IPO) in Hong Kong, the United States and other coun- 
tries outside of China. The Economic Structure Reform relinquished the 
State’s economic ownership of most enterprises to private individuals or 
groups. Ihe Reform fundamentally changed the relations of production in 
the industrial sector. 


2) The Agricultural Sector 


As the capitalist Reformers proceeded to dismantle the state enter- 
prises and rebuild a labor market where labor power could be bought and 
sold, they also moved to dissolve the communes in the countryside. The 
Agricultural Reform enacted the “Family Responsibility System” which 
redistributed land and other collectively owned properties to individual 
peasant households. Small-scale rural industries were divided up and then 
contracted to individuals who had political or family connections. The com- 
mune system was formally dismantled in 1984. The centralized State pur- 
chasing and marketing system, which was responsible for purchasing and 
distributing grain and major agricultural products, also ceased to function. 

The Reformers got the support of the peasants by bribing them with 
a higher purchasing price for grain and for other agricultural products. The 
price for grain purchases within the set quota went up by an average of 25% 
with an additional 50% in bonuses for above quota purchases. From then 
on, peasants became mostly reliant on the market as the main mechanism to 
regulate their production. Urban residents no longer received food rations 
at low prices. Grain production increased rapidly from 1979-1984 with an 


87 


From Victory to Defeat 


increase of 22.5%. It was during this period that de-collectivization took 
place and was eventually completed in 1984. 

After the commune was dissolved, prices of all agricultural inputs 
including chemical fertilizer, water, fuel, and pesticides increased, thus wip- 
ing out peasants’ gains from higher purchasing prices for their output. 

Dissolving the communes was a calculated and necessary move for the 
Reformers. Without collective ownership in the countryside workers could 
no longer form an alliance with the peasants. The Chinese Communist Party 
(representing workers) had formed a close alliance with the peasants when 
fighting the Revolutionary and Civil Wars by promising them land reform. 
Peasants sacrificed their lives and their loved ones when they joined the Red 
Army to fight the guerrilla war. Without the peasants the Chinese Commu- 
nist Party could not have won the revolution. After Liberation, the CCP 
strengthened the worker-peasant alliance by collectivizing agriculture and 
by carrying out policies that mutually benefited workers and peasants. The 
strong alliance between workers and peasants was key to socialist construc- 
tion. When the capitalist Reformers broke the worker-peasant alliance by 
de-collectivizing agriculture, they weakened both the worker and peasant 
resistance against capitalist projects they enacted. 


3) Linking the Chinese Economy to the International Capitalist World 
Market 


Deng Xiaoping, the mastermind of the capitalist “Reform and Open- 
ing Up,” saw correctly that in order for Chinese capital to grow in strength 
it had to cooperate closely with foreign capital. However, since China had 
suffered a long history of imperialist aggression, some Chinese Communist 
Party members who supported the Reform were concerned about whether 
China would be strong enough to remain independent while cooperating 
with foreign capital. The 1980s and early 1990s China’s negotiations with 
the GATT (General Agreement on Tariff and Trade) on terms and condi- 
tions did not go smoothly, because China did not want to give in too much. 
By the mid-1990s and especially after the Asian crisis in 1997, however, the 
Chinese government had to give up many of the conditions it had insisted 
upon and joined the WTO (World Trade Organization) at the end of 2001. 

During the worldwide crisis of overproduction since the late 1970s, 
monopoly capital urgently needed to find new investment opportunities and 


88 


Question VII. 


to further expand markets for its surpluses. Thatcher and Reagan pushed 
forward their neoliberal plan by taking down all barriers for capital expan- 
sion across national borders worldwide. China’s capitalist Reformers were 
just as eager to establish a link with international capital to develop capi- 
talism. Deng bought into the neoliberal ideology of comparative advantage 
and calculated that China’s large pool of disciplined workers could serve 
as an advantage in the international division of labor by concentrating on 
exporting labor-intensive products. The Reformers saw how Taiwan, Hong 
Kong, and others used exports of labor-intensive products to spur economic 
growth and believed China could emulate that model to exponential effect. 
Furthermore, establishing an outside link would garner external support for 
their Reform. 

It is important to point out here that although capitalist reform would 
enable capital to exploit labor, without the “Opening Up” component the 
surplus value could not be realized into profit to achieve capital accumula- 
tion. Therefore, “Capitalist Reform” and “Opening Up” were both necessary 
components for capital accumulation for the new capitalists in China. 

‘The goal of capitalist “Reform and Opening Up” was for China's capi- 
tal to expand and for its capitalist class to gain strength. The strategy has been 
to cooperate with international monopoly capital to achieve rapid capital 
accumulation through high-speed economic growth. In order to achieve its 
goal, the Reformers completely disregarded the suffering of the Chinese peo- 
ple and the damage of high GDP growth on China’s land, natural resources 
and environment. Question VII. will discuss China’s capitalist “Reform and 
Opening Up” in the context of the world of imperialism and the concurrent 
struggle of the world’s laboring class against international monopoly capital. 


Fundamental Changes in the Superstructure 


In order to deconstruct socialism and build capitalism, Reformers 
had to fundamentally change the superstructure as well as the economic 
base. Soon after they seized political power, the new regime rescinded from 
the Constitution workers’ right to strike and basic democratic rights of the 
masses, including free expression, that were gained during the Cultural 
Revolution. During socialist times Mao advocated that the Party should be 
closely connected with the masses and the government initiated various mass 
movements to give the masses the chance to speak out and to express their 


89 


From Victory to Defeat 


opinions. The Three-Anti and the Five-Anti movements, the movement to 
support the Korean War, the Great Leap Forward, and finally the Cultural 
Revolution were all launched to mobilize the masses and encourage them 
to be involved with policies that affected their lives. Through the process of 
mass movements, the masses understood the meaning of the government 
policies and their significance. Mao believed that when the masses under- 
stood and approved of polices to be implemented there was a better chance 
for success. State sponsored mass movements, such as the ones conducted 
in socialist China, are historically very unusual because those in power initi- 
ated and encouraged the involvement of the masses from below. During the 
socialist period periodic mass movements were a method to understand and 
resolve contradictions in society and move society forward. 

However, the implementation of policies under the capitalist reform 
was distinctively different from the past. As a rule, new policies were put 
in place by passing laws and regulations and then pushing them down to 
the masses. It’s understandable that the Reformers did not want to involve 
the masses because the policies they tried to implement were against their 
interests. Since the Reform aimed to fundamentally change class relations 
in society, it generated many contradictions. As contradictions intensified 
there was no way for workers and peasants to express their dissatisfaction as 
in the past through mass discussion and mass action. By the late 1980s many 
of the masses were angered by the corruption of the Reformers and the way 
people were being mistreated. There were also pro-West groups of students 
who demanded “Western style democracy,” or bourgeois expressions of indi- 
vidual “freedoms.” Spontaneous demonstrations began to sprout up. The 
demonstrators mistakenly believed, based on past experience, that the State 
would listen to their grievances and respond to their demands. This was the 
period of time when many reform policies were put in place including pol- 
icies to welcome foreign investment. In order to show that the new regime 
had no tolerance for any mass action from below, and threatened by the 
legions of workers who began organizing to support the initial spontaneous 
protests, they brutally crushed the demonstrations in many cities during the 
spring of 1989. On June 4" the government moved the Army into Beijing 
and killed many of the demonstrators who remained or were fleeing Tianan- 
men Square. As the government took action, people were genuinely shocked 
to witness the People’s Liberation Army soldiers opening fire and massacring 


90 


Question VII. 


unarmed students and workers.*! 

Ideology is, of course, part of the infrastructure. At the same time 
the Reformers proclaimed themselves communists, they began to propagate 
capitalist ideology, popularizing slogans such as: “Let a few get rich first,” 
and “Unemployment is a good thing, because workers work hard if they’re 
afraid of losing their jobs.” The Reformers designed the new industrial orga- 
nization by giving the head of the enterprises new authority to run the fac- 
tories and discipline workers. The capitalist Reform changed the economic 
base by taking away people’s basic rights to a job, a living wage, healthcare, 
housing, retirement and education. A new set of ideologies had to be prop- 
agated to justify their policies. The Reformers proclaimed that socialism was 
inefficient because, “Eating from a big pot breeds laziness.” 

Soon after the Reform began, entrance examinations to higher educa- 
tion were reinstated. The new education policies concentrated on cultivating 
a new elite that would separate themselves from the workers and peasants 
and prepare to be future rulers. Mao’s “three big mountains oppressing Chi- 
nese people” —feudalism, imperialism, and bureaucratic capitalism—under 
the Reform became housing reform, health care reform, and education 
reform. After 30 years of socialism and 40 years of Reform, most workers 
and peasants have seen through the guise. They say, “What we have now 
is not socialism with Chinese characteristics. It is actually capitalism with 
Chinese characteristics.” 

Fundamental changes in superstructure are as important as funda- 
mental changes in the economic base. During socialist times most of the del- 
egates to the National People’s Congress were workers and peasants. Today, 
National People’s Congress delegates are business owners and intellectuals. 
‘They are all of considerable wealth. The last National People’s Congress 
in March 2019 had its annual meeting in Beijing and the delegates were 
guarded with special security fences. Someone commented, “The people’s 
delegates must be kept away from the people.” 

The All-China Women’s Federation made significant contributions 
towards gender equality during socialist times. It promoted model women 
workers and peasants and equal pay for equal work, which raised many 
women’s pay to that of men. After the Reform it has not done anything to 
protect women’s legal rights or to protect women workers from being abused 


*! Before the massacre took place leaders of the pro-West student groups had left 


Tiananmen Square later emigrating to Taiwan and the United States. 


91 


From Victory to Defeat 


and/or assaulted. It no longer advocates for women to “hold up half the sky,” 
as an expression of women’s power during socialism. The current Women’s 
Federation promotes classes that teach petit bourgeoisie women how to cook 
and decorate their houses. 


China’s Capitalist “Reform and Opening Up” and the World of Imperi- 
alism 


1) China’s high rates of GDP growth 


During the 40 years of capitalist “Reform and Opening Up,” China’s 
GDP grew at very impressive rates. In 15 of the 40 years its real rates of GDP 
growth were in the double digits, from 10% to as high as 15.2%, averaging 
around 9% per year during the four decades. (There is a general agreement 
that the official China’s growth rates need to be discounted by 2%.) Even 
though in more recent years China’s GDP growth has slowed to 6-7%, it has 
still been quite a bit above the GDP growth of advanced capitalist countries 
and other developing countries. It’s fair to say that the high rate of GDP 
growth is an accomplishment of the Chinese Reform. However, it is nec- 
essary for us to understand how such rates of growth were achieved and at 
what cost. 

‘The continuing high rates of growth elevated China to become the 
second highest GDP producing country in the world, second only to the 
United States. This change has had significant consequences on the world 
of imperialism—both on global monopoly capital and on the international 
working class. Moreover, the consequences of high rates of GDP growth 
on China as a country and on its people are tremendous and far-reaching. 
Capitalists all over the world and, of course, in China celebrate the great suc- 
cess of China’s Reform. How do we, contemporary revolutionaries, evaluate 
China’s Reform from a broad, long-term perspective? 

Technically speaking, China’s high GDP growth came from a combi- 
nation of high rates of export and investment growth. GDP is the aggregate 
of consumer spending (C), investment spending (I), government spending 
(G), and net exports (exports minus imports, or X I). GDP = C+1+G+ 
X—I. China’s high GDP growth was mainly derived from high net export 
growth rates and high investment growth rates. Both of these high rates of 
growth were accomplished by calculated policies of international monop- 


92 


Question VII. 


oly capital and by the new Chinese regime representing the new capitalist 
class. The cooperation between them formally began at the end of 2001 
when China joined the WTO and agreed to play by the rules determined 
by international monopoly capital. From then on they both competed and 
cooperated. The capitalist “Reform and Opening Up” linked China to world 
imperialism. Its GDP was able to grow at amazingly high rates through high 
export growth rates and high investment growth rates. Below we will see 
how these high rates were accomplished and discuss their consequences. 


2) The New International Division of Labor and China’s Export Growth 


‘The international division of labor among countries before World War 
II and up to the 1970s was very clear. The imperialist countries produced 
industrial goods and sold them to colonial and semi-colonial countries, 
while the colonial and semi-colonial countries supplied raw materials and 
energy needed for the industrialization in imperialist countries. The impe- 
rialist countries used any means necessary, including military invasion and 
occupation, to stop colonial and semi-colonial countries from industrializa- 
tion so they could maintain their domination over the sources of material 
and energy they needed for their industries, and at the same time maintain 
and expand the market for their industrial products. Ceaselessly searching 
for raw material and energy and relentlessly pushing to expand markets have 
been the reasons for endless wars, brutal pillage, and destruction of people 
and land in the modern era. 

By the second half of the 1970s imperialism was in crisis. The rate of 
growth stagnated, there were serious problems of overcapacity in all fields of 
manufacturing due to overinvestment and inadequate aggregate demand. 
In other words, it was not that people did not need more material goods 
to satisfy their needs but that they did not have the money to buy them. 
Under capitalism the markets do not recognize needs; needs only count 
when backed with purchasing power to become demand. ‘The grain stores 
overflow but people are hungry. Additionally, organized workers in imperi- 
alist countries grew in strength, and they fought for higher wages and better 
benefits, both of which ate into corporation profits. A new strategy of capital 
accumulation was urgently needed. 

‘Thus began the neoliberal strategy of capital accumulation that started 
with the policies of Thatcher and Reagan, designed by global monopoly cap- 


23 


From Victory to Defeat 


ital. The neoliberal strategy was and is to liberalize capital by breaking down 
all the barriers across national borders for capital investment and trade. The 
content of neoliberal imperialism included privatization, liberalization and 
de-regulation. These concrete policies intended to and succeeded in breaking 
down the barriers in colonial and semi-colonial countries set up to resist for- 
eign trade and foreign investment. Privatization aimed to dissolve nationally 
owned industries in these countries for foreign companies to acquire. Liber- 
alization and de-regulation lowered restrictions on foreign capital, including 
rules to protect labor and the environment. In 1995 the World Trade Orga- 
nization (WTO) was established to replace the General Agreement on Tariff 
and Trade (GATT). The WTO broadened its scope to include not only tariff 
and trade but also cross border investment of multinational corporations. 
By this time Western corporations, especially US corporations had already 
expanded their investment into other countries. 

Neoliberal strategy has helped increase the speed and extend the scope 
of the expansion of multinational corporations and facilitate a new interna- 
tional division of labor. When international monopoly capital was free to 
go wherever it wanted, it gave multinational corporations the freedom to 
select their production location. Moreover, with the help of international 
trade and investment organizations, such as the WTO and the International 
Monetary Fund, these powerful multinational corporations grasped the 
power to internationalize their production and the freedom to split up the 
production of each product to be produced in different countries. With the 
internationalization of production came the new international division of 
labor. Imperialist countries no longer wanted the exclusive right to produce 
industrial products. Instead, colonized and semi-colonial countries would 
receive orders to produce parts of a product or certain categories of prod- 
ucts. Thus, since the late 20" century, the internationalization of production 
added another dimension of imperialist aggression and exploitation to the 
pillaging of raw material and energy from colonial and semi-colonial coun- 
tries, and the push to further expand markets. 

The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development 
(OECD) describes how international production, trade and investments are 
increasingly organized today within “global value chains” (GVCs), where 
different stages of the production process are located across different coun- 


94 


Question VII. 


tries.” According to OECD, setting up the global value chain “motivates 
companies to restructure their operations internationally through outsourc- 
ing offshoring of activities.” The grand design of GVCs is made within the 
powerful multinational corporations with careful considerations regarding 
trade and financial arrangements. Countries where production actually takes 
place do not have any say in this grand design; they can only compete with 
one another by offering the multinationals the best conditions, including 
the low tax rates (even tax exemption for extended periods), high allowance 
for profit repatriation, suitable infrastructure for transporting goods, sim- 
plified bureaucratic procedure, little or no environmental regulation, basic 
education and appropriate training for workers, and strict rules against labor 
organizing—and state repression to enforce such rules. Additionally mul- 
tinational corporations also enjoy the right to leave all of their production 
waste on foreign soil. 

China’s capitalist Reform and how it linked China to international 
monopoly capital came at an opportune time. But the timing was not 
something that happened by chance. Back in the 1960s four client states 
(or territories) of the United States—Taiwan, South Korea, Hong Kong, 
and Singapore—were chosen as a testing ground for the export-led growth 
model. Multinational corporations from the US and Japan invested in these 
countries (territories) for the sole purpose of exporting their products. The 
export-led growth strategy created the myth that when developing coun- 
tries increase their exports at all costs, growth and prosperity surely follows. 
In fact, the export-led growth benefited the imperialist countries and their 
monopoly capital far more than the countries that adopted this strategy. In 
the 1970s the United States passed environmental protection laws, and com- 
panies that wanted to circumvent these laws and take advantage of cheap 
labor moved their production to Taiwan, South Korea, etc. Two large cor- 
porations, RCA and Atari, are good examples. These companies and many 
others that followed seriously polluted Taiwan’s natural environment and 
severely injured the workers who worked with toxic materials in the facto- 
ries. Worker struggles against RCA for justice for the serious and potentially 
fatal health consequences they suffered continue today. In the meantime 
RCA has been sold and has become part of a French company. 

Deng Xiaoping praised Taiwan's export-led growth model and vowed 


* OECD Official website: OECD.org 


95 


From Victory to Defeat 


that China could do better with its exponentially larger labor force. His 
famous southern investigation tour cemented the strategy of export-led 
growth for China. Shenzhen, originally a fishing village, was chosen to be 
the center of production for exports. Today, Shenzhen, together with the rest 
of Pearl River Delta, has become the industrial hub of 4.2 million people, 
most of who migrated from all over China, and where the notorious Fox- 
conn Company is headquartered. 

‘The concrete example of the making of iPhones shows how the new 
international division of labor benefited Apple, an American high-tech mul- 
tinational. Apple introduced its new product in 2007 and sold three million 
iPhones that year, 5.3 million the next and eleven million in 2009. A working 
paper published by the Asian Development Bank in 2011 gave a breakdown 
of how Apple benefited from parceling out its production through a global 
value chain. The iPhone was assembled in China with its different compo- 
nents produced in the United States, Japan and South Korea. The working 
paper showed that the completed iPhone sold in the United States for $500 
in 2009. $178.96 of the $500 was actual manufacturing cost, and the rest, 
or $321, was what it called the gross profit. Gross profit might not be an 
accurate term, because it included the cost of selling the iPhone, including 
advertising costs. A large proportion of the $178.96 manufacturing cost was 
what Foxconn paid for importing parts from the above-mentioned coun- 
tries and a small profit accrued by Foxconn after subtracting other produc- 
tion related costs. Worker wages in each assembled iPhone constituted only 
$6.50, a merely 3.6% of the total manufacturing costs. 

In addition to the extremely polluting production of crude steel, so 
too is the production of the inordinate amounts of clothing, shoes, toys, 
bicycles, air-conditioner units, washing machines, solar panels, and many 
other household items produced solely for the purpose for export. All these 
products are exported and arrive in the US and other imperialist countries 
clean and free of pollutants—the toxic waste is left behind. Rarely do we 
see any analysis that relates China’s pollution problem to the role China has 
played in the international division of labor in the current capitalist system. 
However, a recent article, “A Dirty Secret China’s Greatest Imports: Carbon 
Emission,” by Earth is worth noting. The article begins with: “The U.S. and 
much of the Western world have a dirty secret. While we claim to be work- 
ing diligently to decrease our emissions and switch to cleaner, non-fossil 
fuel energies, we are actually just exporting emissions to other countries, 


96 


Question VII. 


most notably China.” The article explains that while “the world turns toward 
China to be its dirty manufacturer, we all clean up our books, pushing our 
emissions and energy consumption onto them. We let China produce and 
ship our goods, and then say, “Who me? I don’t produce emissions. I’ve cut 
mine. China is to blame.’”*” 

‘The article continues to say that the United States has been decreasing 
its total energy consumption, dropping from 359 BTU per person per year 
in 1978 to 308 BTU per person per year in 2009, and while it has reduced 
its coal consumption (from 50% to 45% of its electricity fuel mix), it has 
increased its coal exports from 26 million short tons in 2009 to 40 million 
short tons in 2010 reaching 10% of its total coal production. US coal exports 
to China during the first half of 2010 was 1,000 times that of the first half 
of 2009. The article continues to say that researchers have determined that 
approximately 1 billion tons of carbon dioxide emissions in China are from 
the production of products destined for export to other countries.” 


3) High Level and High Growth Rate Investment is Unsustainable 


High levels and high rates of investment growth have been the other 
important contributors for China high GDP growth rate. On November 27, 
2012 the IMF published a working paper entitled, “Js China Over-Investing 
and Does it Matter?” The article stated that in 2012 the rate of investment 
in China reached 50% of GDP, and it explored the problems related to 
overinvestment. It asserted that China’s investment level was already high in 
2007 and when the great recession hit the world in 2008-2009, the Chinese 
government began to implement a rescue plan of $586 billion, which was 
spent on a wide range of infrastructure investment projects. Thus, invest- 
ment as percentage of GDP was further raised by 2012 to over 50%. In any 
country, imperialist or colonial/semi-colonial, a 20% of GDP investment 
rate is considered very high. 

‘The government spent the rescue package by vastly expanding infra- 
structure. The high rates of investment resulted in overcapacities in many 
industries. One example was overcapacity in the solar panel industry. 


> hetp://www.earthmagazine.org/article/dirty-secretchinas-greatest-import-car- 
bonemissions 


4 Tbid. 


* International Monetary Fund working paper No. 12/277, November 21, 
2012. 


97 


From Victory to Defeat 


According to an article published by McKinsey & Company on “China’s 
Great Rebalancing/ Promise and Peril,” in less than a decade China’s solar 
panel industry went from non-existent to become dominant in the world. 
The ten largest Chinese manufacturers today account for more than 60% of 
global solar panel production and in 2010, 96% of the solar panels China 
produced were exported. The article continues to say the problem of this 
growth was almost entirely production driven.” Solar panel production is 
also highly polluting. 

Additionally, housing stock expanded rapidly, reaching a level far 
above people’s ability to buy, causing the fear of a housing bubble burst. 
From the government rescue package came the extensive construction of the 
transportation network, which included 30,000 kilometers (18,600 miles) of 
high-speed railway and 35,000 km (22,000 miles) of highways.*’ The major 
infrastructure construction facilitated the flow of goods and people. At the 
same time, tremendous waste resulted from over-building. Many four-lane 
highways built in small towns are still deserted, while whole cities and towns 
with rows and rows of residential and commercial buildings, roads, hotels 
and exhibition centers stand empty. This overinvestment has represented an 
extreme imbalance in the Chinese economy and caused tremendous damage 
to China’s natural environment. Despite the efforts made by the govern- 
ment to rebalance China’s economy to correct the low level of domestic 
consumption, the level has stayed unchanged at around 40% of GDP. The 
level of consumption cannot be raised, because of the low wages of Chinese 
workers. The detrimental effects on China’s environment from 40 years of 
capitalist development will be discussed later, but over-investment has cer- 
tainly been a contributor. One shocking figure can help illustrate the envi- 
ronmental impact of over-investment: China’s cement consumption in three 
years (2011-2013) was more than US cement consumption in the entire 20" 
century.*8 


°° Huang Yasheng, “China’s Great Rebalancing: Promise and Peril,” McKinsey & 
Company, June 2013 

*” Project-Syndicate, April 2, 2019, Project-Syndicate.org and China National High- 
way, Wikipedia 

*8 Swanson, Ana, “How China used more cement in 3 years than the U.S. did in the 
entire 20th Century,” Washington Post, March 24, 2015. 


98 


Question VII. 


4) China Has Become an Imperialist Country—the growth of Chinese 
monopolies and rapid expansion of foreign investment 


It was during the high rates of investment in the past ten years that 
Chinas GDP grew exponentially. China’s economy almost tripled in size 
from 2008 to 2018, with GDP reaching $13.6 trillion. Compared with the 
GDP of Japan, in 2008 China’s GDP was 50% smaller, but by 2016 China's 
GDP was 2.3 times larger than that of Japan.” During this decade China’s 
industries went through mergers and acquisitions and became major giant- 
sized global corporations. In 2018 China had 120 companies on the Fortune 
500 list, just behind US, which had 126 companies, and ahead of Japan, 
which only had 52 companies listed.“ Chinese capital has definitely become 
monopoly capital. 

As China has expanded its GDP and has exported large volumes of 
products abroad it has needed more raw materials (including minerals, lum- 
ber and cotton) and energy to feed the production of these products. China 
has invested heavily in Africa, Latin America and the Middle East, as well 
as in Europe and Australia, to secure its supply of raw materials and energy. 
China became a dominant player in the energy sector by 2008. In 2017 
China surpassed the United States and became the largest crude oil importer. 

‘The quest for oil and raw materials has been one important reason to 
further expand its foreign investment. Another reason for China’s expansion 
of its foreign investment was that, since 2008, China ran out of places for 
further infrastructure building. China announced its ambitious “One Belt 
One Road” initiative (BRI) in October 2013 to expand its infrastructure 
investment overseas and to secure its huge demand for energy and raw mate- 
rials, as well as to create commercial relations to expand markets for Chinese 
exports. BRI clearly expressed China’s ambition to expand its influence in 
commerce and trade, as well as in the political sphere. 

The BRI framework calls for open cooperation and direct foreign 
investments (FDI) designed to lay the infrastructure and industrial foun- 
dations to secure and solidify China’s relations with 68 countries on three 
continents. Ihe BRI, once complete, will reach more than 60% of the global 
population, account for nearly one third of world’s GDP and global trade, 


» Zhang Jun, “Chinas Decade of Sweeping Economic Change, Project Syndicate,” Apr 
2, 2019, 1-4. 


6 ChinaDaily.com.cn, July 20, 2018. 


99 


From Victory to Defeat 


and 75% of its known energy reserves. Under this plan, China will be linked 
to Europe through Central Asia and Russia; to the Middle East through 
Central Asia; and to Southeast Asia, South Asia, and the Indian Ocean via 
both land and sea routes. The BRI involves the funding and construction 
of a system of roads, railways, oil and natural gas pipelines, fiber-optic and 
communication systems, ports, and airports that will have implications on 
global energy security in the coming decades.” 

So far, China has built and paid for seven dams in Cambodia, which 
generate half of the electricity in that country. Sri Lanka borrowed $1 bil- 
lion from China to build a deep-water port. China owns it and is leasing it 
to Sri Lanka for the next 99 years. South Africa borrowed $1.5 billion to 
build a coal-fired power plant—one of 63 such power plants China has built 
around the world. Zambia borrowed $94 million to build a large soccer 
stadium.” So far the total amount of China’s investments and loans is still 
rather small, but China possesses large stores of US dollars and other foreign 
currencies and the has potential to expand foreign investment along the BRI 
and beyond. 


5) The Impact of China’s Development in the Past Forty Years 


Following 30 years of socialism, China joined the world of imperialism 
and has become an imperialist country. This development has tremendously 
benefited international monopoly capital. China has provided a space for 
international monopoly to expand and a space for overflowing commodities, 
generated by the fevered capacity to produce, thus helping moderate the cri- 
sis of the capitalist system for the time being. However, this development has 
been destructive to the international working class and has further deterio- 
rated the world’s natural environment. China’s large work force joining the 
international division of labor exerted strong downward pressure on wages 
in all countries, especially in imperialist countries. Capitalists in imperialist 
countries have been able to take advantage of global production and shipped 
manufacturing jobs to China and other countries that followed its model. 


$! Sucharita Gopal, Joshua Pitts, Zhongshu Li, Kevin P. Gallagher, James G. Bald- 
win and William N. Kring, “Fueling Global Energy Finance: The Emergence of China 
[; Global Energy Investment,” lttps://www.mdpi.com/1996-1073/11/10/2804/ 
P 


° “How China became a Super Power,” China Rules, https://www.nytimes.com/inter- 


active/2018/11/18/world/asia/world-built-by-china.html 


100 


Question VII. 


This development at least partially explains the stagnated wages and 
reduced benefits in the United States and other imperialist countries. In the 
neoliberal phase of imperialism, where capital is free to choose its location of 
production, it has become increasingly difficult for workers to engage capital 
in their struggles for higher wages and better benefits: capital can simply 
pack up and leave. During the past several decades, workers in the United 
States have not been able to make any advances or even defend what they 
once fought for and won. 

As wages started to rise in China from strong demand for labor in the 
last decade due to fast growing GDP and export manufacturing, businesses 
moved from China’s coastal provinces to smaller cities in Central China to 
seek lower wages. Oversea investors from Taiwan and Hong Kong that had 
contracted local businesses to produce began moving to other low-wage 
countries, such as Sri Lanka and Bangladesh for textile and clothing pro- 
duction. Many local business owners who lost their contracts simply closed 
down their shops and disappeared with unpaid wages owed to workers and 
unpaid loans owed to the banks. Low-wage Foxconn workers, who made 
iPhones for Apple, now work for Huawei, a Chinese owned high-tech firm 
that out-competed Apple in the Chinese market. Now Huawei just found 
the new place for its production and marketing: India. 

In the process of China becoming another imperialist country, inter- 
national monopoly has gained and the international working class has lost. 
China provided the imperialist world with large numbers of industrial work- 
ers, thus lowering wages for monopoly capital. Moreover, China exported 
low-priced consumer goods to other imperialist countries, dampening the 
pressure of inflation. However, the growth of China’s immense industrial 
workforce will eventually strengthen the international working class. The 
new international division of labor has created greater potential for unit- 
ing working class struggles across all countries. It is up to the proletariat to 
seize the opportunity to realize such potential. China’s capitalist “Reform 
and Opening Up” gave international monopoly capital the opportunity to 
incorporate China into the world of imperialism. It came at an opportune 
time to rescue global capitalism from its crisis. Now, 40 years later, with 
added capacity for production and the generation of even bigger surpluses, 
the crisis of global capitalism has only become deeper and more entrenched. 
Additionally, the global environmental crisis has worsened and become more 
critical. 


101 


From Victory to Defeat 


China’s Capitalist “Reform and Opening Up” and China’s Working 
Class Struggles 


During the forty years of capitalist “Reform and Opening Up,” Chi- 
nas new ruling class created a large—perhaps the largest—army of the 
unemployed in history (by any measurable standard). At the same time, 
the Reform transformed hundreds of millions of peasants into the fastest 
growing population of industrial workers. In the past four decades the focal 
point of class struggle has shifted from the old industrial centers during the 
socialist construction, to the center of export industries located in the south- 
ern coastal cities. During the same forty years, Chinese society went through 
tremendous changes, which have resulted in deep internal contradictions 
that have permeated throughout China’s cities and countryside. These con- 
tradictions in Chinese society have manifested in different intense struggles, 
which will be discussed in another section. 


1) The Reform Created a Large Army of Unemployed 


In the 1990s, former state-owned factories went through rounds of 
restructuring that laid off tens of millions of workers, who only received a 
very small monthly payment below the minimum amount needed to sub- 
sist. The newly unemployed workers were also deprived of any healthcare. 
Hospitals and health clinics that previously provided medical care to workers 
began charging high fees to cover their own costs as required by the Reform. 
In 2004 I visited Shenyang, which had been a flourishing industrial city in 
northeast China where heavy industry had been concentrated. By that time 
it looked like a ghost town where stores, nurseries, barbershops, and bath- 
houses were all shut down. Unemployed workers lined the street selling a 
few household items including family pets for cash but nobody was buying. 
‘These workers displayed “for hire” signs offering to work any odd job but no 
one could afford to hire them. 

A friend who accompanied me on that trip took me to the home of 
an unemployed worker. Everyone in the household—the husband, the wife, 
and the son—were all unemployed. The family tried to make a few RMB 
(Chinese dollars) by selling some food items on the street, but the small cart 
they had bought was overturned by a strong wind and everything was lost. 
The husband told me that he suffered from very bad stomach pain. When 
he went to the hospital the doctor ordered an expensive test and after pay- 


102 


Question VII. 


ing for the test he had no money left to buy the medicine. The wife was a 
factory worker all of her adult life, but her job was terminated. The son was 
over thirty years old and a discharged soldier. He said that he felt his life was 
over. Tens of millions of laid-off workers in many industrial cities all over 
China were in similar situations. All of them tried to find some way to eke 
out a living. Some did succeed as street vendors, taxi drivers or food servers. 
Many women became prostitutes. Like their Third World sisters and broth- 
ers, they became part of the underground economy. These former proud 
factory workers have to constantly look for buyers for their labor power just 
to survive. At the same time, they face relentless harassment and abuse from 
the police. The police often charge them with some trumped up violation 
and force them to pay a fine that wipes out the entire earnings from their 
day’s work. 

‘The privatization of state-owned enterprises has been a major compo- 
nent of China’s capitalist Reform. In the early 1990s hundreds of thousands 
of factories in older industrial cities all over China started going through 
rounds of restructuring. Many laid-off workers fought to save the factories 
where they had worked for decades from being closed or sold. Workers pro- 
tected the machinery and equipment from being moved away and destroyed. 
But they could not sustain their struggle against the powerful political forces 
of privatization. By the late 1990s and early 2000s the big wave of privatiza- 
tion was over, but there were still continuing efforts to take over what still 
remained. Below is one example how in 2005 workers successfully resisted 
the take-over of one large steel complex in Jilin Province. 

Tonghua Steel was a state-owned enterprise under the jurisdiction of 
the Jilin Provincial State Asset Supervision and Administration Commis- 
sion. It was a large steel enterprise and had once employed 30,000 workers. 
In 2005 Jianlong, China’ largest private investment company, bought 40% 
of Tonghua Steel shares. After the sale of stocks, Tonghua became a joint- 
stock corporation and Jianlong’s management took over key management 
positions. Tonghua began losing money once Jianglong acquired the shares. 
Then in 2008 the financial crisis hit the steel industry hard, and Tonghua 
lost even more money that year. Worker wages were cut to an average of 
300 RMB per month, much below the 600-800 subsistence wage level. In 
March 2009, Jianlong made the decision to sell its shareholdings. When 
the news was announced, Tonghua’s workers celebrated with firecrackers. 
Then the workers worked hard, determined to save the enterprise. By early 


103 


From Victory to Defeat 


2009, when the price of steel recovered somewhat, the enterprise showed a 
small profit, causing Jianlong to decide to take over enterprise again. Jilin’s 
provincial government reached a secret agreement with Jianlong to acquire 
a controlling share of Tonghua. Contrary to normal procedures, which were 
to announce the acquisition in a meeting of the staff and the workers’ repre- 
sentative congress ahead of the deal, the news was announced after the deal 
had been made. Upon the announcement, a number of Tonghua’s general 
managers resigned on the spot. 

How the deal was made and announced infuriated the workers. Early 
on the morning after the announcement, 3,000 workers and their families 
staged a demonstration in front of the main office carrying signs reading, 
“Jianlong, get out of Tonghua’ and calling for a mass demonstration. A large 
number of demonstrators gathered and proceeded to the metallurgy section 
of the factory compound and succeeded in blocking the railway lines leading 
to the blast furnaces. By the early afternoon they had blocked all the railways 
and shut down all seven blast furnaces. The whole production of Tonghua 
came to a halt. When Chen, the newly appointed General Manager of Ton- 
ghua Steel from Jianlong Group, arrived with a team to talk to middle man- 
agement and staff representatives about ways to resume operations, a group 
of demonstrators rushed in and dragged Chen out of the room and later 
beat him to death. By early evening, nearly ten thousand workers gathered; 
they did not allow any government officials to enter the building. At around 
9:00 in the evening, Tonghua Steel announced on television that the Jilin 
provincial government asked Jianlong to withdraw and never to participate 
in restructuring Tonghua Steel again. This is a rare case in which workers 
successfully blocked the privatization of their factory. Then, only one month 
later in August 2009, workers in Linzhou Steel in Henan Province were also 
able to block Fengbao Iron and Steel Company from acquiring their steel 
enterprise. 

During the early stage of Reform, worker struggles against capital 
were mostly in factories built during the socialist period. The struggles were 
against the privatization of those enterprises and against labor reform turn- 
ing labor power into a commodity by establishing a labor market where 
workers were hired and fired. In later stages, the struggles moved to post-so- 
cialist built factories. 


104 


Question VII. 


2) The Growth of Industrial Workers and their Struggles 


After the Reformers broke up the communes in the countryside, peas- 
ants and their families could no longer live on selling what they could grow 
on their small plots of land. Moreover, agricultural infrastructure, such as 
the irrigation and drainage systems built during socialist times, fell apart 
due to lack of maintenance. Other services that existed under the commune, 
such as healthcare and education, which had supported peasants’ daily lives 
and their overall welfare, all disappeared for lack of funding. In the early 
2000s I visited a village in Henan Province. Peasants in this village had used 
their increased income from selling grain at higher prices in the mid-1980s 
and built some nice houses. They had exhausted their savings and were left 
without reserves to help them through the lean years when their incomes 
dropped due to higher priced farm inputs. The primary school house (just 
a little hut) in the village was about to collapse because its walls were full 
of cracks. The teacher of the school had not been paid for over a year even 
though she continued to teach. 

These kinds of conditions force many younger family members to 
leave home to find jobs so they can send some of their wages home. Older 
parents and small children stay behind to guard their small piece of land. 
During the early 1990s the number of young people leaving home to work 
in the export industries in coastal cities totaled about 100 million—now 
their numbers have increased to around 300 million. Today there are still 
around 300 million peasants remaining in the countryside who barely sur- 
vive on the money their children send home. They often have to abandon 
farming or just grow some vegetables for their own consumption. As a result 
China’s scarce arable land has become even scarcer. Their lives are very hard 
and some do not survive. There have been reports (not frequent but not 
rare either) where grandparents have poisoned their grandchildren with pes- 
ticides and then committed suicide. I still remember vividly what an old 
peasant said to me: “I followed Chairman Mao in his fight against capital- 
ism. But I did not really know what capitalism was. Now I know. This is the 
capitalism Chairman Mao warned us about.” 

While the former state enterprises laid off their workers during their 
restructuring, a total 300 million people, about the size of the workforce in 
the entire European Union, migrated from the countryside to cities to work. 
When the new regime wanted to use exports of low-priced labor-intensified 


105 


From Victory to Defeat 


products to spur economic growth, it welcomed subcontracting firms owned 
by overseas Chinese in Taiwan, Hong Kong and Singapore to invest in cities 
in Guangdong, Fujian and other coastal cities and in the city of Shenzhen. 

Large numbers of male and female migrants work in these factories 
producing exports. Mostly men work in construction projects and in trans- 
portation infrastructure, while women work in restaurants, hotels, and/or as 
domestic workers for the wealthy and many become prostitutes. The sub- 
contracting businesses produce clothing, household items, footwear, sport 
equipment, toys, and electronics. They also make computer components 
and/or assemble phones and tablets, many of which are sold abroad under 
multinational brand names. Workers in these factories, especially during the 
early years, were given very little training and as a result suffered many work- 
place injuries on a daily basis. In the early decades of the 1990s, hospitals in 
these cities reported that so many fingers were being severed by accidents at 
the workplace that they were “collecting human fingers by the bushel” every 
day. Workers in electronic factories are often exposed to highly toxic mate- 
rials, such as solvents that contain benzene and trichloroethylene. Many of 
these workers became seriously ill with liver and lung damage. The State’s 
interest is not in enacting or enforcing any vigorous regulations to prevent 
toxic work environments. 

The brutal factory life of these migrant workers is well document- 
ed.“ They often work 12 to 14 hours a day plus overtime. During busy 
times when deliveries are due, overtime is imposed on the workers. Even 
though the overtime stipulated in their contracts is often limited to 36 
hours a month, the reality is that it could be several times over that limit, 
to as many as 200 or more hours a month. Their wages average about $30 
a month (1,800 RMB) but have been rising in recent years—doubling or 
even tripling—mostly due to workers fighting back and negative interna- 
tional publicity. The result is that subcontracting firms are moving to other 
low-wage countries, such as Vietnam, Bangladesh, and Sri Lanka, as well 
as to central China. Most of these subcontracting firms are small but there 
are also larger factories employing tens of thousands or even hundreds of 
thousands or more workers. For example, the aforementioned Foxconn, is 


°° Shenzhen was a small fishing village that was converted into a special economic 
zone. 


“ https://www.dissentmagazine.org/article/condition-working-class-shenzhen-peas- 
antworkers-authoritarian-consumerism 


106 


Question VII. 


a subcontracting firm owned by the Honghai corporation based in Taiwan, 
which produces computers and other IT products for Apple, Intel, Dell, 
and other IT multinationals, and employs 1.3 million workers in its various 
factories. Not all of them are located in Shenzhen and Guangdong, because 
some of Foxconn’s production has moved to central China to avoid paying 
higher wages. On the surface, these mega-factories look like better places to 
work. However, management in these factories enforces strict work rules to 
maximize worker productivity. The pace of work is at breakneck speed and 
has resulted in well-publicized tragedies. In 2010, 18 workers who could no 
longer endure the oppressive work regimen committed suicide by jumping 
from high-rise dormitory buildings. 14 of them died.” 

Most of the labor struggles of these young migrant workers took the 
form of small strikes concerning wages and working conditions and were 
settled quickly. However, there were also strikes that lasted longer and had a 
significant impact on production. One example is the Nanhai Honda strike 
in 2010, which lasted from May 17 through June 4. According to a China 
Labor Watch report, since Nanhai Honda was a transmission plant its strike 
stopped the production of four auto assembly plants and also sparked strikes 
in other foreign-owned car factories. On May 31, 2010, 200 thugs affil- 
iated with the local trade union physically assaulted a group of workers. 
‘The incident made the Nanhai strike known nationally, well publicized in 
national and local newspapers, and garnered support from Chinese aca- 
demics. Honda Corporation management finally gave in and agreed to the 
workers’ demand, granting an immediate 33% wage increase. The victory 
at Nanhai Honda encouraged workers in other auto factories; China Labor 
Watch reported that it spread to at least eleven other auto factories.” 

China Labor Watch also reported that the strikes at auto companies 
that followed the Honda strike all took place in the period of social unrest 
in China beginning in the early 1990s. ‘The report said that the Ministry 
of Public Security recorded 8,700 incidents of social unrest nationwide in 
1993. That number increased to 74,000 in 2004 and then 87,000 in 2005. 
By 2006 the Ministry stopped publishing numbers for fear of negative 


& Ibid. 
6 China Labor Watch, October 25, 2010, http://www.chinalaborwatch.org/ news- 
cast/60 


% “The Strike Wave,” http://www.chinalaborwatch.org/newscast/60 


107 


From Victory to Defeat 


impact. 

Obviously the Nanhai Honda strike was organized, but workers in 
China do not actually have a representative labor union. The All-China 
Federation of Trade Unions (ACFTU) is a semi-official government union, 
often discouraging workers from taking strike actions and is not usually on 
the workers’ side in labor disputes or during labor negotiations. ‘The strike at 
Nanhai Honda and many other workplaces in China seems to indicate that 
labor struggles do not require the same kinds of labor unions as in Western 
capitalist countries. Continued struggles at the factories have raised workers’ 
wages and benefits. Higher wages have resulted in relocating manufacturing 
to cheaper countries. These relocations caused many factory closings with 
owners fleeing and leaving behind unpaid wages and debts. 

Commentators on labor struggles in China recognize the difference 
between migrant worker struggles in the newer export manufacturing indus- 
tries in the coastal cities and earlier struggles of older workers in factories 
built during the socialist period. Labor struggles in the export industries 
have been more focused on economic issues, such as wages, benefits, and 
working conditions. Worker struggles in factories built before the Reform 
were also about economic issues but showed more political consciousness 
and ideology. Since such workers built the factories themselves, they believed 
the factories belonged to them. ‘The anti-privatization worker struggles in 
former state-owned factories, though rarely successful, are of political signif- 
icance. These struggles show the political consciousness of workers and the 
legacy of socialism. However, during the last few years, workers’ struggles in 
factories built in the post-Reform era have begun to turn more political and 
ideological. This is a critical turning point in worker struggle in China. 

‘The turning point occurred in part because young intellectuals began 
to develop a deeper relationship with the working class. During the post-Re- 
form era, universities continued offering classes on the theory of Marx, 
Lenin, and Mao. However, most of these classes taught by party officials 
often deliberately misinterpreted the true meaning of these revolutionary 
theories and histories. Students, most of whom were the precious offspring 
of the new bourgeois class, showed little interest or, because of the relentless 
black propaganda, were even suspicious toward communist theory. But there 
were still a small handful of true Marxists tutoring students in study groups 


8 Tbid. 


108 


Question VII. 


outside their regular class. 

These study groups at Qinghua University and Beijing University 
started in the 1990s and continued year after year, impacting different grad- 
uating classes. The study groups did more than read books because they 
understood Mao's teaching on the importance of practice. As part of their 
study they went to visit older workers and learned from them about their 
lives during socialism and the hardship and struggle these workers were 
going through in the post-Reform era. During their summer and winter 
vacations, they went to work in factories in the coastal areas on a short- 
term basis. Working in factories—even for a short time—they learned about 
the lives and struggles of this new generation of migrant workers. Through 
the workers’ experiences the students learned the fundamental differences 
between socialism and capitalism. 

During the past two decades a number of young men and young 
women (perhaps a few hundred), who joined similar study groups in dif 
ferent universities, matured from what they learned in their studies and 
from the oppression and struggles they witnessed in the society at large— 
and made a qualitative leap. They decided to devote themselves to serve the 
working masses. They supported workers by helping them resolve problems 
and difficulties they encountered in their lives, and they provided services 
and organized cultural and recreational activities and study groups. I read 
how students from a Chinese medical school gave massages to long-distance 
truck drivers. These actions connected the young intellectuals to the work- 
ers. They united in struggle. This unity was something the State feared most 
because the Chinese Communist Party succeeded in the revolution by estab- 
lishing a strong link between the workers and peasants and revolutionary 
young intellectuals. 

In late 2018 and early 2019, some of these young men and women 
supported workers at the Jasic wielding equipment factory in their efforts to 
form a union. Throughout these struggles the young intellectuals vowed to 
serve the working masses, stating: “We will always be the sons and daughters 
of the workers and peasants.” Throughout their struggle, over 100 workers, 
students, and others were arrested or disappeared by the government. Their 
arrests and disappearances are closely related to the increasingly oppressive 
policies and tightening grip on security by the CCP and its Chairman Xi 
Jinping. Moreover, the capitalist regime tightened students’ activities on 
university campuses, prohibiting activities such as study groups, open dis- 


109 


From Victory to Defeat 


cussions, and publications. These new oppressive policies have had a chill- 
ing effect on students and other intellectuals on the Left. However, as long 
as exploitation and oppression exist, many intellectuals will continue their 
struggle with the exploited and oppressed masses. This has been the moral 
fabric of intellectuals in China’s long revolutionary history, a tradition from 
the student May 4 Movement in the early 20" century, throughout the long 
struggle to Liberation, to the current post-Reform period. 


Impact of China’s Capitalist “Reform and Opening Up” on China's 
Land, Resources, and Environment 


As explained earlier, China has very little arable land. Collective agri- 
culture during socialist times enabled peasants to spend numerous hours 
improving the quality of the land. During socialist times China was able to 
feed its large and growing population by doubling the yield of the available 
land. During those years, peasants worked long hours to prepare the soil 
before planting. They used treated waste from humans, animals, and vege- 
tation to carefully prepare organic compost. Even when chemical fertilizer 
became available in the 1970s, peasants only applied it sparingly. 

However, after the communes collapsed, the quality of soil in the 
countryside steadily deteriorated. As stated above, many young people left 
the countryside to find jobs to send money home to support their families. 
Those who remained have grown old, and many of them no longer work 
in the fields. They hire teams who own farm machinery to do the tilling, 
planting, and harvesting. These peasants often apply too much chemical 
fertilizer hoping to have a bigger yield in the short-term. The excessive use 
of chemical fertilizer has not only destroyed the natural nutrients of the land 
and turned it into hard pieces of caked soil, large quantities of chemical fer- 
tilizer also flows from the fields into the rivers. Overuse of chemical fertilizer 
in agriculture is a serious problem worldwide, but in China the problem 
has reached extreme proportions.” The agricultural research extensions that 
used to provide the peasants with technical assistance on farming under the 
commune system no longer exist. 

China has very limited access to fresh water and is one of the 13 coun- 
tries with the lowest per capita water supply. After four decades of rapid 


® https://www.chinadialogue.net/article/show/single/ch/5153-The-damaging- 
cdachaliout-Cltnecefr6lisee and pesticide tse 


110 


Question VII. 


economic growth after the capitalist “Reform and Opening Up,” water in 
85% of China's six biggest river systems is now undrinkable—even after 
treatment. The percentage of groundwater that is polluted reached 60% in 
2013.” Since large quantities of water have been used for industrial pur- 
poses, currently 400 out of China’s 600 major cities do not have adequate 
water for their residents. Cities continue to dig deeper for water causing 
depletion of groundwater. China’s Ministry of Water Resources stated that 
this practice not only further aggravates the water shortage, but also lowers 
water quality and increases the risk of earthquakes and landslides.”! 

Air pollution in China is just as serious. In northern cities air pollu- 
tion has reached extremely toxic levels. Readings of particulate matter no 
more than 2.5 microns in size (PM2.5), the most harmful type of toxic smog 
for people to breathe, routinely reaches 40 times the maximum level allowed 
by the World Health Organization. 

Although this kind of short-term predatory high growth strategy 
brought high profits for China's capitalists, it has deprived China of the 


potential for long-term sustainable development. 


China’s Capitalist “Reform and Opening Up” and the Deep Internal 
Contradictions 


The capitalist “Reform and Opening Up” in the past 40 years has 
resulted in a polarized society that is full of a wide range of serious contra- 
dictions. The Reform created major class contradictions between the broad 
masses of toiling people, especially workers and peasants and the small num- 
ber (2% to 3% of the population) of powerful political elites who also own 
and control tremendous economic power and resources: the new bourgeoi- 
sie. Between these two contending forces are the petit bourgeoisie who com- 
prise less than 30% of the population but total 300 million people—nearly 
matching the total population of the United States or two-thirds of the total 
population of the European Union. The petit bourgeoisie—who are the small 
to middle-sized business owners, technocrats, housing developers, realtors, 
middle-level management and government officials, middle-level military 
personnel, academic personnel in universities, and others—have benefited 


” The Economist, May 17%-23" 2014, 44. 


™ “Chinas Water Shortage to Hit Danger Limit in 2030,” People’s Daily Online: http:// 
english. peopledaily.com.cn/ 


111 


From Victory to Defeat 


from the Reform. The petit bourgeoisie in large and medium-sized cities live 
comfortably. They usually own comfortable apartments, stocks and other 
properties. They have extra money to spend on cars and other luxury items 
and on travel. In 2018 the number of Chinese tourists who traveled abroad 
totaled 140 million. Many of them spent lavishly on buying name brand 
consumer goods. ‘The petit bourgeoisie provides a buffer between the very 
small number of extremely wealthy bureaucrats/capitalists and the broad 
masses of working people. 

Many migrants who work in the service and construction indus- 
tries are also poorly treated. In the construction business, as a rule, workers 
receive their full pay only after the project is completed. During the months 
while construction is in progress, workers usually receive some subsistence 
wages on a weekly or monthly basis. However, many construction contrac- 
tors refuse to pay workers what they are owed upon completion of the proj- 
ect. There have been reported cases that instead of paying the workers as they 
demand, police are called in to use brutal force to disperse them. This kind of 
extreme abuse and violence committed by private employers, often with the 
cooperation of the police and local government officials, is commonplace. 

Peasants suffer similar abuses in the countryside. Two journalists, 
Chen Guidi and Chun Tao, investigated and reported on many shocking 
cases in Anhui Province. In their Chinese Peasant Investigation Report, Chen 
and Chun documented how village officials beat peasants to death.” Pub- 
lished in 2003, their book was quickly disappeared from circulation. In 
more recent years, there have been many large-scale enclosure movements 
through the “Urbanization of the Countryside Project” where incidents of 
land grabbing and evictions have become commonplace. Any resistance on 
the part of peasants and urban dwellers is brutally suppressed. Since “regu- 
lations” prohibit confiscation of farmland, developers—with the aid of local 
authorities—deliberately destroy crops in the fields. One incident I heard 
about (though not substantiated) was of a developer who poured cement 
over the almost harvestable wheat, depriving peasants the last bit of income 
they would have otherwise received. Enclosure movements are widespread. 
Many urban dwellers have been evicted, even if their houses were only built 
a few years before, in designated residential areas, according to the city’s plan. 
City authorities simply draw up different plans for developers and bulldoze 


”? Chinese Peasant Investigation Report (Zhongguo Nongming Diao Cha) 114. 
& Pp a4 gming 


112 


Question VII. 


people’s houses without adequate compensation. 

Most of these abuses are not reported; there are few places people can 
go to seek justice because the court system is just as corrupt. Many, if not 
most, officials of town and city governments and of different administrative 
units in the countryside have close connections to underground criminals, 
including mafia-type organizations. Criminal activities such as kidnapping, 
the operation of prostitution rings and gambling houses, trafficking in ille- 
gal drugs, and other illegal activities require and receive the cooperation 
and protection of the police. Ordinary people know all too well that the 
police can no longer be trusted to uphold and enforce the law against these 
criminals. The connection between criminal elements in society and legal 
authorities go both ways because the police and private businesses often hire 
gangsters to do their dirty work. 

Over the past decades, as the burden of environmental pollution 
on people and their communities have become more serious, people have 
increasingly organized to block the construction of power plants, chemical 
factories, and garbage incinerators. Demonstrations against environmental 
pollution often involve tens of thousands and even hundreds of thousands of 
people. One such demonstration happened in September 2014 in Pingjiang 
County, Hunan Province against the construction of a coal-powered electric 
plant. The town closed down its high school so students could participate. 
More than 10,000 people showed up to the demonstration. The demonstra- 
tors held up large signs with messages to Xi Jinping: 


“Xi Jinping, do not sacrifice the environment for economic devel- 
opment.” 


And: 


“Xi Jinping, we want green mountains and clear water. We do not 
want mountains of gold or silver.” 


Another large demonstration in Zigong City, Sichuan Province at the 
end of January 2019 also involved more than ten thousand people protest- 
ing underground fracking for natural gas. The city experienced three earth- 
quakes where two people died. The residents suspected the fracking had 
caused earthquakes and demonstrators surrounded the city administration 
building to demand that fracking be suspended. The demonstrators finally 


113 


From Victory to Defeat 


dispersed after those responsible promised to abide by the suspension.” 

‘The large numbers of protests happening in China reflect many previ- 
ously unresolved contradictions and the development of new contradictions. 
As living and working conditions continue to deteriorate, and as corrupt 
and abusive government officials continue to be uninterested in finding any 
real solutions, China’s masses are increasingly frustrated and angry. All the 
issues, including land grabbing, factory closings, and environmental pollu- 
tion, are problems the masses face every day. These issues manifest in strikes 
at the workplace and demonstrations on the streets and in the countryside. 
These ongoing incidents show that the contradictions in Chinese society 
have reached a heightened level. Xi Jinping has repeatedly called for building 
a harmonious society, but most people regard these calls as meaningless rhet- 
oric. As the contradictions between the Reformers and the masses intensify, 
the government uses more repressive measures to suppress the voice and 
actions of the masses. 

Chinese society has gone through tremendous changes during the cap- 
italist “Reform and Opening Up” in the past four decades. The Left outside 
of China have been actively discussing and debating the meaning and signif- 
icance of the Chinese revolution, its socialist construction and the capitalist 
reform, and how this history has impacted the world. The Left in China, 
quite apart from those outside, has also engaged in serious discussions and 
debates on these same issues. A short discussion follows on how the Left in 
China evaluates the legacy of the socialist past, how they analyze China's 
current situation, and their outlook for China’s future. 

‘The overwhelming majority of the Chinese people are very proud of 
China’s liberation in 1949 and the years of socialist construction; they hold 
dear the legacy of Mao Zedong and socialism. For this reason, the capitalists 
who knowingly betrayed Mao and what he stood for have had to continue to 
use him as a symbol to be worshiped. But most Chinese people have genu- 
ine affection toward Mao. Many of them celebrate Mao’s birthday year after 
year, and the people designated Mao’s birthday on December 26 as “People’s 
Day.” Tens of thousands of people from all over China gather in Shaoshan, 
Hunan (Mao’ birthplace) to celebrate every year. In 2018, tens of thousands 
of people arrived in Shaoshan on December 25™ and stayed up all night in 
the large outdoor square to celebrate Mao’s 125" birthday. They brought 


? https://www.chinadialogue.net/article/show/single/ch/5153-The-damaging-truth 
about-Chinese-fertiliser-and-pesticide-use 


114 


Question VII. 


flowers, large banners and many red flags, and they shouted slogans and sang 
revolutionary songs throughout the night. 

During the early years of the Reform, several respected old commu- 
nist party loyalists, who no longer played active roles within the Party, kept 
writing letters to the Political Bureau voicing their opinions on the reform 
policies and presented what they thought were constructive criticisms. Their 
letters and opinions were ignored by those in power. These party loyalists 
gave hope to some on the Left that there were still healthy elements within 
the Party. Thus, some within the Left believed that the Party was not totally 
hopeless, and they formed a faction that called for reform from within. 

Even before the nationalist revolution in 1911 to overthrow the Qing 
Dynasty, nationalism and patriotism has historically played an important role 
in China’s political changes because China had been invaded and occupied, 
its people exploited and oppressed, by imperialist powers for more than a 
century. Mao was a patriot in his youth. There has always been agreement in 
China that it needs to be strong in order to fend off aggression from outside. 
The question was only how to make China strong. When Japan invaded 
China, Mao called on the country to cooperate with the Kuomintang to 
defeat the Japanese, because the survival of China as a nation was at stake. 
After the Japanese surrendered, the Chinese Communist Party continued 
to lead the fight against the Kuomintang until Liberation in 1949. Many 
progressive youth joined the fight against the Kuomintang for patriotic rea- 
sons, because they believed that the Chinese Communist Party was the only 
hope for China’s survival. Those who actually believed in communism were 
not the majority. The two-line struggle within the Communist Party during 
the socialist construction reflected the divide between the revolutionaries 
and those who were fundamentally nationalists. The capitalist roaders rep- 
resented by Liu Shaoqi and Deng Xiaoping believed capitalism could build 
a strong China. Deng’s famous saying was: “It doesn’t matter whether a cat 
is white or black, as long as it catches mice,” meaning: “It does not matter 
whether the system is capitalism or socialism. The one that makes China 
strong is the best system.” 

‘The results of forty years of capitalism in China are obvious. What 
most people see depends on whether they have benefited from or have been 
hurt by the four decades of capitalism. In other words, their economic inter- 
est is an important determinant. However, whether they support the capi- 
talist Reform or not is not entirely based on their personal gains or losses; 


115 


From Victory to Defeat 


nationalism and patriotism play a role, especially among China’s intellectu- 
als. Many people who are part of the forces against the current regime are 
very concerned about the effects of forty years of capitalism on China as a 
country and on the Chinese people as a whole. They have seen how capi- 
talism changed Chinese society in many negative and detrimental ways: the 
abuse and corruption committed by a powerful few, the deterioration of 
China’s land and natural resources, the destruction of socialist values, the 
hideous crimes against vulnerable people, and the rampant spread of the 
underworld of drugs and prostitution. In other words, they have real con- 
cern about the future of China and the Chinese people. They actively join 
the struggle against unfair treatment of workers, environmental pollution, 
genetically engineered foods, and many others. 

‘The current opposition forces are not a homogenous group. Within 
the opposition there are those with nationalist tendencies who believe the 
principal contradiction in China today is between China and other impe- 
rialist countries, especially the United States. They believe any political tur- 
moil within China invites imperialist countries to intervene. They may dis- 
like many aspects of the current regime such the treatment of workers, the 
environmental problems, the rampant corruption, and the fact China has 
become an extremely polarized country. But they believe the current regime 
is the only political force that can protect China’s sovereignty. They see how 
aggressive China has been toward other less developed countries in Africa, 
Latin America, and other Asian countries, yet they do not condemn China 
for being another imperialist country. Instead, they are the apologists for 
China’s actions and argue that China treats these countries in a “kinder” 
way compared to other imperialists. They tend to turn a blind eye to the fact 
that China is pillaging the resources of these countries and oppressing their 
people. 

Those with nationalist tendencies strongly defend the interests of 
Chinese capital. They are very keen on how the CCP handles its economic 
relations with other imperialist countries. They do not want the CCP to 
give in too much when dealing with other imperialist powers, especially the 
United States. They watch carefully how Xi Jinping negotiates with the US 
in current trade talks. In turn, the CCP has to be mindful of their influence 
on public opinion. 

An online recent article on Redchina.cn.net is a good representation 
of the views of this group: “Promoting the Anti-America Patriotic National 


116 


Question VII. 


Front’ is the Most Important Mission of the Maoists in China today.” 

In this article the author stated that the Left should not focus their 
struggle on supporting Jasic workers; instead, the focus should be fighting 
the United States, which opposes China’s “2025 Made in China” ambition.” 
The article continued to say that this patriotic front should unite not only 
those who believe that only socialism can save China but also those (includ- 
ing overseas Chinese) who truly have the interests of China in their hearts, 
even if these patriotic people may still have illusions about capitalism. The 
author uses the historical example of China’s national front against the Japa- 
nese and calls for another protracted war against the American imperialists. 

‘The article was quickly refuted by another article entitled: “Contradic- 
tion Between Classes is the Principal and the Most Important Contradiction in 
China,” authored by Zhen Yan. The author asserted that any change happens 
mainly through internal factors. He wrote that during socialist years, China 
was strong and no imperialist country dared to interfere with China’s inter- 
nal affairs because the socialist government had the full support of its people. 
Zhen Yan refuted the previous article's attempt to equate China’s current 
situation with the time of the Japanese invasion and occupation by saying 
that there is not one foreign soldier in China today and the danger Chinese 
people face is not external but internal. The article says true Maoists today 
should firmly oppose imperialism and revisionism, which is represented by 
the elite bureaucratic capitalist class. He also said that for quite a while now, 
false Maoists have tried to protect those in power (the current Communist 
Party) and make imperialism the principal enemy, ignoring the fact that we 
cannot fight imperialism without simultaneously fighting revisionism. Zhen 
Yan’s analysis is correct because the interests of China’s bureaucratic capitalist 
class are closely linked to global monopoly capital represented by imperialist 
powers. 

Since those with nationalist tendencies believe only the current regime 
can maintain the stability and unity of China, they continue to think that 
there are healthy elements within the Party and therefore continue to advo- 
cate for reform from within the Party. They once placed their hopes in Bo 
Xilai, a prominent government official who advocated for reform. As the 
mayor of Chongqing (a major city and province in southwest China), Bo 


4 The “2025 Made in China” aan is for China to achieve technological advancement 
so it can produce all high-tech products. The article written by Qu Wei Cun Zhen 
appeared in: http://www.redchinacn.net/portal.php?mod=view&aid=38336 


117 


From Victory to Defeat 


put forth Chongqing as a model that advocated for a more equal distribu- 
tion of income, more public services (such as public housing), cleaning up 
government corruption, and cutting down police brutality. However, the 
party power center could not tolerate even such moderate reforms proposed 
by Bo and got rid of him on some trumped-up charges. Yet it is still difficult 
for those who advocate reform from within to give up their hopes. Since Xi 
Jinping, more often than previous capitalist rulers, likes to quote Mao, those 
who place their delusional hopes in Xi listen to his speeches to count how 
many times Xi mentions Mao. In the meantime, Xi has tightened his control 
by using punitive measures to prevent the contradictions below the surface 
from boiling over. 


China and Chinese People in the Future of World Socialist Revolu- 
tion 


Though forces that resist the oppression have grown in strength, they 
are still not strong enough to counter the reactionary forces. In the next few 
decades China will become a critical center for the struggle between global 
monopoly capital and massive forces of the proletariat. 

As noted in the section explaining China’s “Reform and Opening Up,” 
changes in China in the past forty years especially since 2000 have greatly 
benefited imperialism at the expense of the working people. In 2011 China 
surpassed the United States to become the largest manufacturing country in 
the world with an industrial workforce of 112 million people, far exceeding 
those of other industrial countries. Not only does China have the largest 
number of industrial workers, it also has the largest number of labor strug- 
gles involving wage disputes, work stoppages and other work-related issues. 
In addition to workers’ struggles, there have also been many other economic 
and social contradictions in China, including environmental problems, cor- 
ruption problems, police brutality, and other forms of oppression. I have 
no doubt that many of these contradictions will continue to surface and 
sharpen in the coming decades. In a world where capital has become glo- 
balized, workers’ struggles and people’s struggles also need to be more con- 
nected. In the decades ahead, with all the struggles that are yet to come, 
China will be the center of these struggles. 


118 


Conclusion 


Conclusion 


What can we learn from the history of China from the past century 
since the 1911 Revolution that overthrew the Qing dynasty? 

We have learned that people in oppressed nations can rise up and 
liberate themselves. During the past one hundred years, Chinese people’s 
hopes and aspirations have been for China to be a sovereign nation and to be 
treated equally among other nations. The 1911 Revolution was a democratic 
revolution of the old type, led by the capitalist class with the goal of destroy- 
ing feudalism. That revolution failed when Chiang Kai-shek betrayed the 
revolution. As Mao explained in New Democratic Revolution, the democratic 
revolution of the old type could not succeed because the capitalist class in 
semi-colonial and semi-feudal countries was too weak, and they had to rely 
on the landlord class to rule the country. For that reason, it is not possible to 
have a democratic revolution led by the capitalist class in a semi-colonial and 
semi-feudal country to end feudalism. Mao wrote that only a democratic 
revolution of the new type, led by the proletariat, could end feudalism. If 
the democratic revolution is led by the proletariat then socialist revolution 
will surely follow. 

The Chinese Communist Party, founded in 1921 and led by the pro- 
letariat, built a strong alliance with China’s peasantry and formed a broad 
coalition with the national bourgeoisie. They succeeded in the liberation 
of China on October 1, 1949 when Mao declared that the Chinese people 
had stood up and a new China was born. Revolutionaries around the world 
celebrated with the Chinese people the possibility of building a new society 
where people would be free of domination and oppression both from within 
and from without. The socialist construction that followed inspired many 
revolutionaries, especially those in poor and oppressed nations. In 1956 
the Chinese Communist Party galvanized revolutionaries all over the world 
when it dared to challenge the revisionists of the Communist Party of the 
Soviet Union. Then in 1966, China took another critical step in leading the 
anti-revisionist fight by launching the Great Proletarian Cultural Revolution 
to struggle against the revisionists within the Chinese Communist Party. The 
intensive anti-revisionist struggle during the ten years of the Cultural Rev- 
olution exposed the revisionists within the CCP and the capitalist projects 
they had tried to implement. Although the struggle between the revolution- 


119 


From Victory to Defeat 


ary line and the revisionist line was at times confusing, chaotic, and even 
violent, it demonstrated clearly that if socialist revolution were to proceed, 
the struggle against revisionism would be unavoidable—and continuing rev- 
olution necessary. The Cultural Revolution also showed the content, form, 
and strategy of such an anti-revisionist struggle in a country going through 
socialist transition. 

During that period in China, the people followed Mao and proceeded 
to develop socialism, which liberated them from economic deprivation, class 
oppression, foreign aggression, and political persecution. Socialist construc- 
tion gave rise to great enthusiasm among Chinese people to put forth their 
best efforts to build a China with hope, pride, and aspirations. Within a 
short period of two decades Chinese workers, peasants, and intellectuals 
built a solid foundation for industry and agriculture for their long-term sus- 
tainable development. At the same time China produced enough economic 
wealth to improve the livelihood and well-being of a large and growing pop- 
ulation, providing them with basic economic security, education, health, 
and culture. 

Mao’s revolutionary line was defeated after his death in 1976, when 
the revisionists in the CCP seized political power and began their capital- 
ist Reform. After four decades of capitalist development, high rates of eco- 
nomic growth impressed some people enough to believe that China was 
on its way to becoming an economic superpower. Those who have such an 
outlook must believe that imperialism—as it has existed in the last hundred 
years—still has a long way to go. It is helpful to recall that by the last thirty 
years of the 20 century, global monopoly capital had run out of places to 
expand, requiring as its solution opening up more space for monopoly capi- 
tal.”° China’s capitalist Reform came at just the right time to provide a wide- 
open space, free of litter and with abundant, cheap, and disciplined labor for 


” Tn the late 1990s when the Asian crisis began, the problem of overcapacity (which 
had persisted from the early 1970s) worsened. The automobile industry is a good 
example of the seriousness of the problem. The Wall Street Journal reported on August 
25, 1997 that the worldwide capacity of car production reached 70 million vehi- 
cles—32% more than consumers were buying. A 1998 article in The Economist said 
that Japanese carmakers had the capacity to produce 14 million cars, but far less than 
half that number could be sold on the domestic market. The same article stated, 
“Europe is as much plagued by over-capacity as Japan. Car production there is grow- 
ing by 4% a year but demand by only 1.5 percent.” (The Economist, March 21, 1998, 
p. i Now, in 2018, the overcapacity of automobile industry is plaguing China as 
well. 


120 


Conclusion 


global monopoly capital. 

Monopoly capital, together with Chinese capital, indeed expanded— 
not only in China, but also in India, Brazil, the rest of Latin America and 
Asia, and the whole Africa continent. 

Forty years later, global monopoly again is running out of places to 
expand. In the meantime, rich and poor countries have been flooded with 
“made in China” products. China’s land, river, and natural resources are 
exhausted and its environment thoroughly polluted from overproduction 
and overinvestment. Some experts say that even if it were possible, it would 
take much longer than forty years for the environment to recover to where 
it was forty years ago. The so-called “China’s miracle” or “the miracle of 
monopoly capital” of the past four decades cannot be repeated. 

The future of the Chinese people, and in fact the future of all peo- 
ple in the world and the natural world itself, depends how long we allow 
monopoly capital to dominate the future of the earth and of humanity. That 
is to say, our future depends on how revolutionaries can unite the interna- 
tional working class to resolutely destroy international monopoly capital, to 
end capitalism and to build socialism. 


121 


RELATED BOOKS FROM FOREIGN LANGUAGES PRESS 


Deng-yuan Hsu & Pao-yu Ching 


Rethinking Socialism 


SoS SOCIALISM: 
SoctaList TRANSITION? 


Denc-yuan Hsu & Pao-yu Caine 


‘This essay succinctly answers the question "Is China 
still socialist?" and tries to give an objective analysis of 
the reasons behind the defeat of socialism in China. 


‘This essay was revised with a new introduction by pro- 
fessor Pao-yu Ching. 





J. Moufawad-Paul 
Critique of Maoist Reason 






4 Utilizing the term "critique" in the philosophical 
= sense implied by Kant, Sartre, Mbembe, and others, J. 
mm ™ Moufawad-Paul offers an exacting analysis of the dif- 
Pere TT ferent trends that emerged out of the victory, develop- 
ment, and ultimate defeat of the Chinese revolution. 
Markedly and intentionally different from a polemic, 
Critique of Maoist Reason is a text for all who consider 
themselves "Maoists," as it clarifies and contextualizes 
various modes of thought within or associated with 
Maoism. Moufawad-Paul's latest contribution satisfies 
its intention to sharpen Maoist thinking through rig- 
orous investigation. 


—_ 


N DW HK w 


8 


COLLECTION “COLORFUL CLAssIcs” 


. Marxism-Leninism-Maoism Basic Course —- Communist Party 


of India (Maoist) 


Also available in German, Arabic, Italian 


. Philosophical Trends in the Feminist Movement — Anuradha 


Ghandy 


. Minimanual of the Urban Guerrilla — Carlos Marighella 


The Communist Necessity — J. Moufawad-Paul 


. Maoists in India: Writings & Interviews — Azad 
. Five Golden Rays — Mao Zedong 


. Stand for Socialism against Modern Revisionism — Armando 


Liwanag 


. Strategy for the Liberation of Palestine — PFLP 


9. Against Avakianism — Ajith 


10. Specific Characterics of our People’s War — Jose Maria Sison 


11. Rethinking Socialism: What is Socialist Transition? — Deng-Yu- 


an Hsu & Pao-yu Ching 


12. Fedai Guerillas Speak on Armed Struggle in Iran — Dehghani, 


Ahmadzadeh, Habash, Pouyan, Ashraf 


13. Revolutionary Works — Seamus Costello 


14. Urban Perspective - Communist Party of India (Maoist) 


15. Five Essays on Philosophy - Mao Zedong 
16. Post-Modernism Today — Siraj 
17. The National Question — Ibrahim Kaypakkaya 


_ 


COLLECTION “New Roaps” 


. From Victory to Defeat: China’ Socialist Road and Capitalist Rever- 


sal — Pao-yu Ching 


. Silage Choppers and Snake Spirits - Dao-yuan Chou 
3. Which East is Red? — Andrew Smith 
4. Mao Zedong’ “On Contradiction” Study Companion — Redspark 


Collective 


. Critique of Maoist Reason — J. Moufawad-Paul 


COLLECTION “Works OF MAOISM” 


. Collected Works (1968-1987) — Communist Party of Peru 
. Selected Works, Vol. VI — Mao Tse-tung 


COLLECTION “FOUNDATIONS” 


. The Foundations of Leninism — Joseph Stalin 
. Value, Price and Profit & Wage Labour and Capital — Karl Marx 


. Reform or Revolution? — Rosa Luxemburg 


https://foreignlanguages. press 
https://redspark.nu